Innovation and investments in environmentally sound infrastructure and technologies can reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and enhance resilience to climate change (very high confidence). Innovation and change can expand the availability and/ or effectiveness of adaptation and mitigation options. For example, investments in low-carbon and carbon-neutral energy technologies can reduce the energy intensity of economic development, the carbon intensity of energy, GHG emissions, and the long-term costs of mitigation. Similarly, new technologies and infrastructure can increase the resilience of human systems while reducing adverse impacts on natural systems. Investments in technology and infrastructure rely on an enabling policy environment, access to finance and technology and broader economic development that builds capacity (Table 4.1, Section 4.4). {WGII SPM C-2, Table SPM.1, Table TS.8, WGIII SPM.4.1, Table SPM.2, TS.3.1.1, TS 3.1.2, TS.3.2.1}
Adaptation and mitigation are constrained by the inertia of global and regional trends in economic development, GHG emissions, resource consumption, infrastructure and settlement patterns, institutional behaviour and technology (medium evidence, high agreement).
Vulnerability to climate change, GHG emissions, and the capacity for adaptation and mitigation are strongly influenced by livelihoods, lifestyles, behaviour and culture (medium evidence, medium agreement) (Table 4.1). Shifts toward more energy-intensive lifestyles can contribute to higher energy and resource consumption, driving greater energy production and GHG emissions and increasing mitigation costs. In contrast, emissions can be substantially lowered through changes in consumption patterns (see 4.3 for details). The social acceptability and/or effectiveness of climate policies are influenced by the extent to which they incentivize or depend on regionally appropriate changes in lifestyles or behaviours. Similarly, livelihoods that depend on climate-sensitive sectors or resources may be particularly vulnerable to climate change and climate change policies. Economic development and urbanization of landscapes exposed to climate hazards may increase the exposure of human settlements and reduce the resilience of natural systems. {WGII SPM A-2, SPM B-2, Table SPM.1, TS A-1, TS A-2, TS C-1, TS C-2, 16.3.2.7, WGIII SPM.4.2, TS.2.2. 4.2}
For many regions and sectors, enhanced capacities to mitigate and adapt are part of the foundation essential for managing climate change risks (high confidence). Such capacities are place-and context-specific and therefore there is no single approach for reducing risk that is appropriate across all settings. For example, developing nations with low income levels have the lowest financial, technological and institutional capacities to pursue low-carbon, climate-resilient development pathways. Although developed nations generally have greater relative capacity to manage the risks of climate change, such capacity does not necessarily translate into the implementation of adaptation and mitigation options. {WGII SPM B-1, SPM B-2, TS B-1, 16.3.1.1, 16.3.2, 16.5, WGIII SPM.5.1, TS.4.3, TS.4.5, 4.6}
Improving institutions as well as enhancing coordination and cooperation in governance can help overcome regional constraints associated with mitigation, adaptation and disaster risk reduction (very high confidence). Despite the presence of a wide array of multilateral, national and sub-national institutions focused on adaptation and mitigation, global GHG emissions continue to increase and identified adaptation needs have not been adequately addressed. The implementation of effective adaptation and mitigation options may necessitate new institutions and institutional arrangements that span multiple scales (medium confidence) (Table 4.1). {WGII SPM B-2, TS C-1, 16.3.2.4, 16.8, WGIII SPM.4.2.5, SPM.5.1, SPM.5.2, TS.1, TS.3.1.3, TS.4.1, TS.4.2, TS.4.4}
EditTable 4.1
EditConstraining Factor | Potential Implications for Adaptation | Potential Implications for Mitigation |
---|---|---|
Adverse externalities of population growth and urbanization | Increase exposure of human populations to climate variability and change as well as demands for, and pressures on, natural resources and ecosystem services {WGII 16.3.2.3, Box 16-3} | Drive economic growth, energy demand and energy consumption, resulting in increases in greenhouse gas emissions {WGIII SPM.3} |
Deficits of knowledge, education, and human capital | Reduce national, institutional and individual perceptions of the risks posed by climate change as well as the costs and benefits of different adaptation options {WGII 16.3.2.1} | Reduce national, institutional and individual risk perception, willingness to change behavioural patterns and practices and to adopt social and technological innovations to reduce emissions {WGIII SPM.3, SPM.5.1, 2.4.1, 3.10.1.5, 4.3.5, 9.8, 11.8.1} |
Divergences in social and cultural attitudes, values and behaviours | Reduce societal consensus regarding climate risk and therefore demand for specific adaptation policies and measures {WGII 16.3.2.7} | Influence emission patterns, societal perceptions of the utility of mitigation policies and technologies, and willingness to pursue sustainable behaviours and technologies {WGIII SPM.2, 2.4.5, 2.6.6.1, 3.7.2.2, 3.9.2, 4.3.4, 5.5.1} |
Challenges in governance and institutional arrangements | Reduce the ability to coordinate adaptation policies and measures and to deliver capacity to actors to plan and implement adaptation {WGII 16.3.2.8} | Undermine policies, incentives and cooperation regarding the development of mitigation policies and the implementation of efficient, carbon-neutral and renewable energy technologies {WGIII SPM.3, SPM 5.2, 4.3.2, 6.4.3, 14.1.3.1, 14.3.2.2, 15.12.2, 16.5.3} |
Lack of access to national and international climate finance | Reduces the scale of investment in adaptation policies and measures and therefore their effectiveness {WGII 16.3.2.5} | Reduces the capacity of developed and, particularly, developing nations to pursue policies and technologies that reduce emissions. {WGIII TS.4.3, 12.6.2, 16.2.2.2} |
Inadequate technology | Reduces the range of available adaptation options as well as their effectiveness in reducing or avoiding risk from increasing rates or magnitudes of climate change {WGII 16.3.2.1} | Slows the rate at which society can reduce the carbon intensity of energy services and transition toward low-carbon and carbon-neutral technologies {WGIII TS.3.1.3, 4.3.6, 6.3.2.2, 11.8.4}
|
Insufficient quality and/or quantity of natural resources | Reduce the coping range of actors, vulnerability to non-climatic factors and potential competition for resources that enhances vulnerability {WGII 16.3.2.3} | Reduce the long-term sustainability of different energy technologies {WGIII 4.3.7, 4.4.1, 11.8.3} |
Adaptation and development deficits | Increase vulnerability to current climate variability as well as future climate change {WGII TS A-1, Table TS 5, 16.3.2.4} | Reduce mitigative capacity and undermine international cooperative efforts on climate owing to a contentious legacy of cooperation on development {WGIII 4.3.1, 4.6.1} |
Inequality | Places the impacts of climate change and the burden of adaptation disproportionately on the most vulnerable and/or transfers them to future generations {WGII TS B-2, Box TS 4, Box 13-1, 16.7} | Constrains the ability for developing nations with low income levels, or different communities or sectors within nations, to contribute to GHG mitigation {WGIII 4.6.2.1} |