945
17
Economics of Adaptation
Coordinating Lead Authors:
Muyeye Chambwera (Zimbabwe), Geoffrey Heal (USA)
Lead Authors:
Carolina Dubeux (Brazil), Stéphane Hallegatte (France), Liza Leclerc (Canada),
Anil Markandya (Spain), Bruce A. McCarl (USA), Reinhard Mechler (Germany/Austria),
James E. Neumann (USA)
Contributing Authors:
Patrice Dumas (France), Samuel Fankhauser (UK), Hans-Martin Füssel (Germany),
Alistair Hunt (UK), Howard Kunreuther (USA), Richard S.J. Tol (UK), Paul Watkiss (UK),
Richard Woodward (USA), David Zilberman (USA)
Review Editors:
Eduardo Calvo (Peru), Ana Iglesias (Spain), Stale Navrud (Norway)
Volunteer Chapter Scientist:
Terrence Kairiza (Zimbabwe)
This chapter should be cited as:
Chambwera
, M., G. Heal, C. Dubeux, S. Hallegatte, L. Leclerc, A. Markandya, B.A. McCarl, R. Mechler, and
J.E. Neumann, 2014: Economics of adaptation. In: Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and
Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment
Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Field, C.B., V.R. Barros, D.J. Dokken, K.J. Mach,
M.D. Mastrandrea, T.E. Bilir, M. Chatterjee, K.L. Ebi, Y.O. Estrada, R.C. Genova, B. Girma, E.S. Kissel, A.N. Levy,
S. MacCracken, P.R. Mastrandrea, and L.L. White (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United
Kingdom and New York, NY, USA, pp. 945-977.
17
946
Executive Summary............................................................................................................................................................ 948
17.1. Background ............................................................................................................................................................. 950
17.2. Economic Aspects of Adaptation ............................................................................................................................ 950
17.2.1. Public and Private Actors in Adaptation Implementation .................................................................................................................. 950
17.2.2. Broad Categorization of Adaptation Strategies ................................................................................................................................ 950
17.2.3. Broad Definition of Benefits and Costs ............................................................................................................................................. 951
17.2.3.1. Ancillary Economic Effects of Adaptation Measures and Policies ...................................................................................... 951
17.2.3.2. Economic Consideration of Ancillary Effects ...................................................................................................................... 951
17.2.4. Adaptation as a Dynamic Issue ......................................................................................................................................................... 951
17.2.5. Practical Adaptation Strategy Attractiveness and Feasibility ............................................................................................................. 951
17.2.6. Adaptation Benefits and Costs, Residual Damage, and Projects ....................................................................................................... 952
17.2.7. A Broader Setting for Adaptation ..................................................................................................................................................... 953
17.2.7.1. Adaptation and Mitigation as Competitive or Complementary Investments ..................................................................... 954
17.2.7.2. Adaptation and Development ........................................................................................................................................... 954
17.3. Decision Making and Economic Context for Adaptation ........................................................................................ 954
17.3.1. Economic Barriers to Adaptation Decision Making ........................................................................................................................... 955
17.3.1.1. Transaction Costs, Information, and Adjustment Costs ...................................................................................................... 955
17.3.1.2. Market Failures and Missing Markets ................................................................................................................................ 955
17.3.1.3. Behavioral Obstacles to Adaptation .................................................................................................................................. 955
17.3.1.4. Ethics and Distributional Issues ......................................................................................................................................... 955
17.3.1.5 Coordination, Government Failures, and Political Economy ............................................................................................... 956
17.3.1.6. Uncertainty ........................................................................................................................................................................ 956
17.3.2. Economic Decision Making with Uncertainty .................................................................................................................................... 956
17.3.2.1. Cost-Benefit Analysis and Related Methods ...................................................................................................................... 956
17.3.2.2. Multi-Metric Decision Making for Adaptation ................................................................................................................... 957
17.3.2.3. Non-Probabilistic Methodologies ...................................................................................................................................... 957
17.4. Costing Adaptation ................................................................................................................................................. 958
17.4.1. Methodological Considerations ........................................................................................................................................................ 958
17.4.1.1. Data Quality and Quantity ................................................................................................................................................. 958
17.4.1.2. Costs and Benefits Are Location-Specific ........................................................................................................................... 958
17.4.1.3. Costs and Benefits Depend on Socioeconomics ................................................................................................................. 959
17.4.1.4. Discount Rates Matter ....................................................................................................................................................... 959
17.4.2. Review of Existing Global Estimates: Gaps and Limitations ............................................................................................................. 959
17.4.3. Consistency between Localized and Global Analyses ....................................................................................................................... 960
17.4.4. Selected Studies on Sectors or Regions ............................................................................................................................................ 960
Table of Contents
947
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
17
17.5. Economic and Related Instruments to Provide Incentives ..................................................................................... 963
17.5.1. Risk Sharing and Risk Transfer, Including Insurance .......................................................................................................................... 964
17.5.2. Payments for Environmental Services ............................................................................................................................................... 964
17.5.3. Improved Resource Pricing and Water Markets ................................................................................................................................ 964
17.5.4. Charges, Subsidies, and Taxes ........................................................................................................................................................... 965
17.5.5. Intellectual Property Rights .............................................................................................................................................................. 966
17.5.6. Innovation and Research & Development Subsidies ......................................................................................................................... 966
17.5.7. The Role of Behavior ......................................................................................................................................................................... 966
References ......................................................................................................................................................................... 966
Frequently Asked Questions
17.1: Given the significant uncertainty about the effects of adaptation measures, can economics
contribute much to decision making in this area? ............................................................................................................................ 954
17.2: Could economic approaches bias adaptation policy and decisions against the interests
of the poor, vulnerable populations, or ecosystems? ........................................................................................................................ 961
17.3: In what ways can economic instruments facilitate adaptation to climate change in developed and developing countries? ............ 965
948
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Executive Summary
In the presence of limited resources and a range of objectives, adaptation strategy choices involve trade-offs among multiple
policy goals (high confidence). The alternative policy goals include development and climate change mitigation. Economics offers valuable
insights into these trade-offs and into the wider consequences of adaptation. It also helps to explain the differences between the potential of
adaptation and its achievement as a function of costs, barriers, behavioral biases, and resources available. {17.2.7.1-2, 17.3.1}
Economic thinking on adaptation has evolved from a focus on cost-benefit analysis and identification of “best economic”
adaptations to the development of multi-metric evaluations including the risk and uncertainty dimensions in order to provide
support to decision makers (high confidence).
Economic analysis is moving away from a unique emphasis on efficiency, market solutions,
and cost-benefit analysis of adaptation to include consideration of non-monetary and non-market measures, risks, inequities and behavioral
biases, and barriers and limits and consideration of ancillary benefits and costs. One role of economics is to contribute information to decision
makers on the benefits and costs, including a number of non-monetary items, and on the equity impacts of alternative actions. It does not
provide a final ranking for policy makers. A narrow focus on quantifiable costs and benefits can bias decisions against the poor and against
ecosystems and those in the future whose values can be excluded or are understated. Sufficiently broad-based approaches, however, can help
avoid such maladaptation. Indeed the evidence shows that maladaptation is a possibility if the evaluation approaches taken are not
comprehensive enough in this sense. {17.2.3, 17.3.2}
The theoretical basis for economic evaluation of adaptation options is clear, and can be and has been applied to support decisions
in practical contexts (medium confidence). There is extensive experience of applying the concepts and methods underlying the economic
framework in non-adaptation contexts, which is useful for designing climate adaptation policies. The limited empirical evidence available
shows a number of cases where desirable adaptation strategies have been identified based on these economic tools. The findings show that
adaptation is highly regional and context specific. Thus the results do not readily permit widespread generalizations about the nature of
attractive adaptation actions. {17.2, 17.4.1-2, 17.4.4}
Both private and public sectors have a role to play in the development and implementation of adaptation measures (high
confidence).
Economic theory and empirical results show that a degree of adaptation will be autonomously carried out by private parties in
response to climate change. However, the private sector alone will often not provide the desirable level of adaptation with some types of actions
not undertaken due to costs, incentives, nature of beneficiaries, and resource requirements. This implies the public sector will need to play a
strong role. There are also other reasons for public action such as overcoming barriers, developing technologies, representing current and future
equity concerns, and other items. {17.2.1, 17.3.1}
The theory and the evidence indicate that adaptation cannot generally overcome all climate change effects (high confidence).
In addition to there being biophysical limits to adaptation, such as the inability to restore outdoor comfort under high temperatures, some
adaptation options will simply be too costly or resource intensive or will be cost ineffective until climate change effects grow to merit investment
costs. Thus the desirability of adaptation options will vary with time and climate change realization. {17.2.2, 17.2.5}
Adaptation generally needs to be seen in the frame of the overall development path of the country, particularly for developing
countries (high confidence).
Development and adaptation can be complementary or competitive. Also development can yield positive
ancillary adaptation effects or co-benefits, provided it takes into account climate change in its design. Adaptation actions can provide significant
co-benefits such as alleviating poverty or enhancing development. Many aspects of economic development also facilitate adaptation to a
changing climate, such as better education and health, and there are adaptation strategies that can yield welfare benefits even in the event of
a constant climate, such as more efficient use of water and more robust crop varieties. Maximizing these synergies requires a close integration
of adaptation actions with existing policies, referred to as “mainstreaming. {17.2.7, 17.2.3.1-2}
Not all adaptation actions are investment-based. Policy actions are also important tools for adaptation (medium confidence).
These include direct research & development (R&D) funding, environmental regulation, economic instruments, and education. Economic
instruments have high potential as flexible tools because they directly and indirectly provide incentives for anticipating and reducing impacts
and can have lower costs in the public budget. These instruments are currently not well explored in an adaptation context apart from risk
949
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
financing instruments. Existing incentives will lead to a set of private adaptation actions. They include risk sharing and transfer mechanisms
(insurance), loans, public-private finance partnerships, payment for environmental services, improved resource pricing (water markets), charges
and subsidies including taxes, norms and regulations, and behavioral modification approaches. These instruments offer some useful possibilities
for addressing climate change but they also have problems of effective implementation that need to be addressed. The problems can be
particularly severe in developing countries. {17.4-5}
Risk financing mechanisms at local, national, regional, and global scales contribute to increasing resilience to climate extremes
and climate variability, but involve major design challenges so as to avoid providing disincentives, causing market failure and
worsening equity situations (medium confidence).
Mechanisms include insurance; reinsurance; micro insurance; and national, regional,
and global risk pools. The public sector often plays a key role as regulator, provider, or insurer of last resort. Risk financing can directly promote
adaptation through providing claim payments after an event and allow for improved decisions under risk pre-event (strong evidence). It can
also directly provide incentives for reducing risk, yet the evidence is weak and the presence of many counteracting factors often leads to
disincentives, which is known as moral hazard. {17.5.1}
Limited evidence indicates a gap between global adaptation needs and the funds available for adaptation (medium confidence).
There is a need for a better assessment of global adaptation costs, funding, and investment. Studies estimating the global costs of adaptation
are characterized by shortcomings in data, methods, and coverage (high confidence). {14.2, 17.4; Tables 17-2, 17-3}
Economics offers a range of techniques appropriate for conducting analysis in the face of uncertainties, and the choice of the
most appropriate technique depends on the nature of the problem and the nature and level of uncertainty (high confidence).
Uncertainty is unavoidable in analyses of adaptation to climate change because of lack of data, the efficacy of adaptation actions, and
uncertainties inherent in forecasting climate change. Approximate approaches are often necessary. There is a strong case for the use of economic
decision making under uncertainty, working with tools such as cost-benefit and related approaches that include time dimensions (real options
techniques), multi-metrics approaches, and non-probabilistic methodologies. There are methodologies that are able to capture non-monetary
effects and distributional impacts, and to reflect ethical considerations. {17.3.2.1-3}
Selected regional and sectoral studies suggest some core considerations and characteristics that should be included in the
economic analyses of adaptation (medium confidence). These desirable characteristics include a broad representation of relevant climate
stressors to ensure robust economic evaluation; consideration of multiple alternatives and/or conditional groupings of adaptation options;
rigorous economic analysis of costs and benefits across the broadest possible market and non-market scope; and a strong focus on support of
practical decision making that incorporates consideration of sources of uncertainty. Few current studies manage to include all of these
considerations. {17.4.3}
950
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
17.1. Background
This chapter assesses the literature on the economics of climate change
adaptation, building on the Fourth Assessment Report (AR4) and the
i
ncreasing role that economic considerations are playing in adaptation
decision making and policy. AR4 provided a limited assessment of the costs
and benefits of adaptation, based on narrow and fragmented sectoral and
regional literature (Adger et al., 2007). Substantial advances have been
made in the economics of climate change adaptation after AR4.
The specific objectives involved in an adaptation effort can be diverse.
One may try to cancel all impacts (negative and positive), maintaining
the status quo. Alternatively one can try to cancel adverse impacts
and capture positive opportunities, so that the welfare gain (or loss) is
maximized (or minimized).
Part of the literature presents adaptation as a continuous, flexible
process, based on learning and adjustments (see, e.g., IPCC, 2012).
Adaptation projects informed by this approach emphasize learning and
experimenting, plus the value of using reversible and adjustable strategies
(Berkhout et al., 2006; McGray et al., 2007; Pelling et al., 2007; Leary et
al., 2008; Hallegatte, 2009; Hallegatte et al., 2011c).
Adaptation action and policy has also advanced since AR4, and the
literature on the economics of adaptation has reflected this. This chapter
builds on other chapters in this assessment—in particular Chapter 2,
which sets the basis for decision making, recognizing economics as a
decision support tool for both public and private actors. The type of
economic approach used depends on factors discussed in Chapter 2,
among others, including the agent making the decision, the nature or
type of decision, the information used to make the decision, who
implements the decision, others affected by the outcomes, and the
values attached to those outcomes. While realizing the linkages
between adaptation and mitigation, the starting point of this chapter
is that adaptation is a given need.
This chapter assesses the scientific literature covering the economic
aspects of adaptation; decision making and the economic context of
adaptation, including economic barriers to adaptation decision making,
and uncertainty; costing adaptation; and the economic and related
instruments to provide incentives for adaptation.
17.2. Economic Aspects of Adaptation
When considering adaptation, economic studies give insight into issues
regarding the roles of various actors in society, the character of
adaptation strategies, the types of benefits and costs involved, the role
of time, and a number of other factors that we discuss in this section.
17.2.1. Public and Private Actors in
Adaptation Implementation
Previous IPCC reports—i.e., the Third Assessment Report (TAR) and
First Assessment Report (FAR)—indicate adaptation actions can be
a
utonomous, planned, or natural. Autonomous actions are undertaken
mostly by private parties while planned can be undertaken by private
or public actors. Natural adaptation is that occurring within the ecosystem
in reaction to climate change but may be subject to human intervention
(see discussion in Section 14.1).
In terms of human actions there are important economic distinctions
regarding the roles of private and public actors. Some adaptation
actions create public goods that benefit many and in such cases the
implementing party cannot typically capture all the gains. For example,
if an individual pays to protect a coastline or develop an improved
irrigation system, the gains generally go to many others. Classical economic
theory (Samuelson, 1954) and experience plus observations regarding
adaptation (Mendelsohn, 2000; Osberghaus et al., 2010a; Wing and Fisher-
Vanden, 2013) indicate that such actions will not receive appropriate
levels of private investment (creating a market failure). In turn, this calls
for public action by elements of broader society (e.g., governments, non-
governmental organizations (NGOs), or international organizations).
Other reasons for public provision or public regulation of certain adaptation
measures that lead to less than a socially desirable level of adaptation
are discussed in Section 17.3.
17.2.2. Broad Categorization of Adaptation Strategies
There are many possible adaptation measures, as indicated in the TAR
and FAR, plus Chapters 14 and 15. In economic terms these include a
mixture of public and private actions taken in both domestic and
international settings. A broad characterization of these and who might
undertake them follows:
Altered patterns of enterprise management, facility investment,
enterprise choice, or resource use (mainly private)
Direct capital investments in public infrastructure (e.g., dams and
water management—mainly public)
Technology development through research (e.g., development of
crop varieties—private and public)
Creation and dissemination of adaptation information (through
extension or other communication vehicles—mainly public)
Human capital enhancement (e.g., investment in education—
private and public)
Redesign or development of adaptation institutions (e.g., altered
forms of insurance—private and public)
Changes in norms and regulations to facilitate autonomous actions
(e.g., altered building codes, technical standards, regulation of
grids/networks/utilities, environmental regulations—mainly public)
Changes in individual behavior (private, with possible public
incentives)
Emergency response procedures and crisis management (mainly
public).
Not all adaptation involves investment or is costly. Some adaptation
measures involve modification of recurring expenditures as opposed to
new investments (replacing depreciated equipment with more adapted
items). Sometimes adaptation involves changes in behaviors and
lifestyles (e.g., due to increased frequency of heat waves).
951
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
17.2.3. Broad Definition of Benefits and Costs
The consequences of adaptation decisions cannot be expressed
comprehensively through standard economic accounting of costs and
revenues. Adaptation decisions can also affect other items such as
income distribution and poverty (Jacoby et al., 2011); the regional
distribution of economic activity, including employment; non-market
factors such as water quality, ecosystem function, and human health;
and social organization and cultural practices.
Adaptation choices have broad ranging and complex impacts on such
issues as:
Macroeconomic performance (see, e.g., Fankhauser and Tol, 1995)
Allocation of funds with a crowding out effect on other climate and
non-climate investments with consequences for future economic
growth (Hallegatte et al., 2007; Hallegatte and Dumas, 2008; Wang
and McCarl, 2013)
Welfare of current and future generations through resource availability
and other non-monetary effects
Risk distributions on all of the above due to routine variability plus
uncertain estimates of the extent of climate change and adaptation
benefits and costs.
A number of these items pose challenges for measurement and certainly
for monetization. Generally this implies that any analysis be multi-metric,
with part in monetary terms and other parts not, and some in precise
quantitative terms and others not (for more discussion see Section
17.3). In view of this, it is reasonable to conclude that an unbiased,
comprehensive analysis would consist of a multi-metric analysis
encompassing cost-benefit and other monetary items plus non-monetary
measures. That analysis would support adaptation decision making.
17.2.3.1. Ancillary Economic Effect
of Adaptation Measures and Policies
In addition to creating an economy that is more resilient to the effects
of climate change, adaptation strategies often have ancillary effects of
substantial importance. These can be positive (co-benefits) or negative
(co-costs). Ancillary effects also arise when actions aimed primarily at
mitigation or non-climate-related matters alter climate adaptation.
Examples include:
Sea walls that protect against sea level rise and at the same time
protect against tsunamis. However, they can have co-costs causing
damages to adjacent regions, fisheries, and mangroves (Frihy, 2001).
Crop varieties that are adapted to climate change have enhanced
resistance to droughts and heat and so also raise productivity in
non-climate change-related droughts and temperature extreme
(Birthal et al., 2011).
Better building insulation that mitigates energy use and associated
greenhouse gas emissions also improves adaptation by protecting
against heat (Sartori and Hestnes, 2007).
Public health measures that adapt to increases in insect-borne
diseases also have health benefits not related to those diseases
(Egbendewe-Mondzozo et al., 2011).
More efficient use of water—adaptation to a drier world—will
also yield benefits under current conditions of water scarcity.
D
evelopment of improved desalination methods has the same
merits (Khan et al., 2009).
Locating infrastructure away from low-lying coastal areas provides
adaption to sea level rise and will also protect against tsunamis.
Reducing the need to use coal-fired power plants through energy
conserving adaptation will also provide mitigation, improve air
quality, and reduce health impacts (Burtraw et al., 2003).
17.2.3.2. Economic Consideration of Ancillary Effects
Many studies argue that co-benefits should be factored into decision
making (e.g., Brouwer and van Ek, 2004; Ebi and Burton, 2008; Qin et
al., 2008; de Bruin et al., 2009a; Kubal et al., 2009; Viguie and Hallegatte,
2012). If a country has a fixed sum of money to allocate between two
competing adaptation projects, and both strategies generate net positive
ancillary effects, then the socially optimal allocation of adaptation
investment will differ from the private optimum and will favor the
activity with the larger direct plus ancillary effects.
17.2.4. Adaptation as a Dynamic Issue
Adaptation is not a static concern. Rather it evolves over time in response
to a changing climate (Hallegatte, 2009). Adaptation is perhaps best
handled via a long-term transitional, continuous, flexible process that
involves learning and adjustment (Berkhout et al., 2006; McGray et al.,
2007; Pelling et al., 2007; Leary et al., 2008; Hallegatte, 2009; Hallegatte
et al., 2011c; IPCC, 2012). Generally the literature indicates that optimal
adaptation and the desirability of particular strategies will vary over
time depending on climate forcing plus other factors such as technology
availability and its maturity (de Bruin et al., 2009b). In the next few
decades, during which time projected temperatures do not vary
substantially across socioeconomic/climate scenarios, adaptation is the
main economic option for dealing with realized climate change. Risk is
also an important aspect, with the longer term being more uncertain
that the near term. Risk-sensitive decisions often include the options of
acting or of waiting (Linquiti and Vonortas, 2012). The issue of options
is discussed further in Beltratti et al. (1998), which covers uncertainty
about future preferences through option values.
Dynamics also are involved with strategy persistence owing to the
decadal to century time scale implications of some adaptation strategies
such as construction of seawalls or discovery of drought-resistant crop
genes. The desirability of investments with upfront costs and persistent
benefits increases when the benefits are long lasting or when climate
change damages accumulate slowly (Agrawala et al., 2011; de Bruin,
2011; Wang and McCarl, 2013). However, maladaptation effects rising
over time are also possible as protecting now can expand investment
in vulnerable areas and worsen future vulnerability (Hallegatte, 2011).
17.2.5. Practical Adaptation Strategy
Attractiveness and Feasibility
Adaptation cannot reasonably overcome all climate change effects
(Parry et al., 2009). A number of factors will limit strategy adoption and
952
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
preclude elimination of all climate change effects. A conceptual way of
looking at this for a given adaptation endeavor is in Figure 17-1. The
first outside circle represents the “adaptation needs, that is, the set of
adaptation actions that would be required to avoid any negative effect
(and capture all positive effects) from climate change. It can be reduced
by climate change mitigation, that is, by limiting the magnitude of
climate change. The second circle represents the subset of adaptation
actions that are possible considering technical and physical limits.
Improving what can be done, for instance, through research and
development, can expand this circle. The area between the first and
second circles is the area of “unavoidable impacts” that one cannot
adapt to (for instance, it is impossible to restore outdoor comfort under
high temperature). The third circle represents the subset of adaptation
actions that are desirable considering limited resources and competing
priorities: some adaptation actions will be technically possible, but
undesirable because they are too expensive and there are better
alternative ways of improving welfare (e.g., investing in health or
education). This circle can be expanded through economic growth,
which increases resources that can be dedicated to adaptation. Finally,
the last circle represents what will be done, taking into account the fact
that market failures or practical, political, or institutional constraints will
make it impossible to implement some desirable actions (see Chapter
15 and Section 17.3). The area between the first and the last circles
represents residual impacts (i.e., the impacts that will remain after
adaptation, because adapting to them is impossible, too expensive, or
impossible owing to some barriers).
This discussion has consequences for timing of adaptation financing,
given continuous changes in climate over time and uncertainties in the
resulting impacts. Mathew et al. (2012) recommend the use of soft,
short-term and reversible adaptation options with co-benefits for local
governments. Giordano (2012) recommends the use of adaptive policies
for modifying infrastructure, which can be robust across a wide range
of plausible futures under climate change. Hochrainer and Mechler
(2011) suggest that tools such as risk pooling may be more cost effective
t
han risk reduction through engineering methods for low-frequency but
high-impact hazards.
Financing adaptation programs is further discussed in the literature
through the lens of distribution of costs. Stern (2006) argues climate
change is characterized by a “double inequity,” with those countries
that are most vulnerable having generally contributed least (on a per
capita basis) to the climate change drivers (Panayotou et al., 2002; Tol
et al., 2004; Mendelsohn et al., 2006; Patz et al., 2007; SEGCC, 2007;
Srinivasan et al., 2008; Füssel, 2010).
Distribution of responsibilities for financing adaptation has been the
subject of lively debate. Füssel et al. (2012) note that answering the
following questions can inform the debate on such burden sharing
issues:
Who pays for adaptation and how much should they contribute
into the adaptation fund, and what criteria are appropriate in
determining this?
Who is eligible for receiving payments from the fund, and which
criteria could be used for prioritizing recipients and for allocating
funds?
Which adaptation measures are eligible for funding, and what are
the conditions and modalities for payment?
How and by whom are such decisions made?
As of now no definitive conclusions have been reached. Table 17-1 sets
out different approaches to defining eligibility for receiving adaptation
funds.
17.2.6. Adaptation Benefits and Costs,
Residual Damage, and Projects
Adaptation benefits are the reduction in damages plus any gains in
climate-related welfare that occur following an adaptation action
(National Research Council, 2010; World Bank, 2010a). Simplistically
described, the cost of adaptation is the cost of any additional investment
needed to adapt to or exploit future climate change (UNFCCC, 2007).
But a full accounting needs to consider the resources spent to develop,
W
h
a
t
i
s
s
u
g
g
e
s
t
e
d
W
h
a
t
w
e
c
a
n
d
o
W
h
a
t
w
e
w
a
n
t
t
o
d
o
What we
will do
Implementation
constraints
A
d
a
p
t
a
t
i
o
n
s
p
a
c
e
T
e
c
h
n
i
c
a
l
a
n
d
p
h
y
s
i
c
a
l
l
i
m
i
t
s
O
b
j
e
c
t
i
v
e
s
Figure 17-1 | The narrowing of adaptation from the space of all possible
adaptations to what will be done. Forces causing the narrowing are listed in black.
Motivation
for action
Relevant climatic factors
Observed and /or
projected climate change
Climate change as well as
natural climate variability
Climate is the
main reason
Defi nition 1: Action occurs
mainly to reduce the risks of
observed or projected climate
change.
Example: Raising of existing
dykes.
Defi nition 2: Action occurs
mainly to reduce risks of climate
change and climate variability.
Example: Building of new dykes
in areas that are currently
unprotected.
Climate is one of
several reasons
Defi nition 3: Actions that
reduce the risks of observed or
projected climate change even
if they are also justifi ed in the
absence of climate change.
Example: Economic
diversifi cation in predominantly
agricultural regions.
Defi nition 4: Actions that reduce
the risks of climate change and
climate variability even if they
are also justifi ed in the absence
of climate change.
Example: Improved public health
services.
Table 17-1 | Four defi nitions of eligible adaptation.
Source: Füssel et al. (2012), adapted from Hallegatte (2008).
953
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
i
mplement, and maintain the adaptation action along with accruing
reduced damages or welfare increases involving monetary and non-
monetary metrics.
Figure 17-2 provides a graphical representation of the link between the
cost of adaptation (on the x-axis) and the residual cost of climate
change (on the y-axis). A fraction of climate change damage can be
reduced at no cost (e.g., by changing sowing dates in the agricultural
sector). With increasing adaptation cost, climate change costs can be
reduced further. In some cases (left-hand panel), sufficiently high
adaptation spending can take residual cost to zero. In other cases (right-
hand panel), some residual cost of climate change is unavoidable.
Economics tells that the optimal level of adaptation equalizes the
marginal adaptation cost and the marginal adaptation benefit, given
by the point on the adaptation curves where the slope is –45°. If barriers
and constraints (see Section 17.3) impose a suboptimal situation, the
marginal costs and benefits of adaptation are not equal, possibly
because there is too much investment in adaptation, so that investing
$1 in adaptation reduces climate change residual cost by less than $1,
or because there is not enough investment in adaptation and investing
$1 more in adaptation would reduce residual cost by more than $1 (the
situation in the right-hand panel).
Defining the costs and benefits of an “adaptation project” raises
conceptual issues. Many actions have an influence on the impact of
climate change without being adaptation projects per se (e.g., enhanced
building norms). Many “adaptation projects have consequences beyond
a reduction in climate change impacts or an increase in welfare from
e
xploiting opportunities (as discussed in the ancillary impacts section).
Defining the adaptation component requires the definition of a baseline
(What would be the impact of climate change in the absence of the
adaptation action? What alternative projects would be implemented in
the absence of climate change?), and the definition of “additionality”—
the amount of additional loss reduction or welfare gain that happens
because of the project. For instance, the building of new infrastructure
may be marginally more costly because of adaptation to climate change
but would still be undertaken without climate change and thus only a
fraction of that cost and the resultant benefits would be labeled as
occurring because of adaptation (see Dessai and Hulme, 2007).
In the climate change context, residual damages are those damages
that remain after adaptation actions are taken. De Bruin et al. (2009b)
and Hof et al. (2009) have examined the relationship between increasing
adaptation effort and diminished residual damages.
17.2.7. A Broader Setting for Adaptation
Adaptation can be complementary to mitigation and to non-climate
policies. An important concern is determining the balance between
spending on adaptation versus that on other investments—mitigation
and non-climate endeavors. Economics indicates the marginal social
returns to all forms of expenditure should be the same, allowing for
distributional impacts which can be done by differential weightings of
benefits and costs to alternative income groups (Musgrave and Musgrave,
1973; Brent, 1996).
Cost of climate change
Adaptation cost
Free
adaptation
Technology limits
(”What we can do” in Figure 17-1)
Optimal balance between adaptation
costs and residual impacts
When full adaptation is possible When full adaptation is not possible
Cost of climate change (no adaptation)
Residual
costs/impacts
Avoided
impacts
Cost of adaptation
(to avoid all impacts)
Suboptimal balance with imperfection
(”What we will do” in Figure 17-1)
Optimal balance
(”What we want to do” in Figure 17-1)
Costs that
cannot be
avoided by
adaptation
Adaptation cost
Cost of climate change
Avoided
impacts
Residual
impacts
Adaptation
costs
Figure 17-2 | Graphical representation of link between the cost of adaptation (on the x-axis) and the residual cost of climate change (on the y-axis). The left panel represents a
case where full adaptation is possible, while the right panel represents a case in which there are unavoidable residual costs.
954
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
17.2.7.1. Adaptation and Mitigation as
Competitive or Complementary Investments
Adaptation and mitigation funding require coordination as they are
competing uses for scarce resources (WGII AR4 Chapter 18; Gawel et al.,
2012). They also compete with consumption and non-climate investments.
For example, some adaptation strategies use land (a shift from crops to
livestock), as does mitigation via afforestation or biofuels, and all three
would reduce ongoing crop production. Nevertheless, considering both
adaptation and mitigation widens the set of actions and lowers the
total cost of climate change (de Bruin et al., 2009a; Koetse and Rietveld,
2012; Wang and McCarl, 2013).
17.2.7.2. Adaptation and Development
There is a relationship between adaptation and socioeconomic
development, particularly in lower income countries (as extensively
discussed in Chapters 10, 13, and 20). In terms of complementarity
between the two, studies show that both development and adaptation
can be enhanced via climate-resilient road development (World Bank,
2009); installation of agricultural investments that enhance income,
heat tolerance, and drought resilience (Butt et al., 2006;Ringer et al.,
2008); or improvements in public health infrastructure that increase
c
apability to deal with climate-enhanced disease and other diseases
(Markandya and Chiabai, 2009; Samet, 2010). In addition, development
in general can increase adaptive capacity through enhancements in
human and other capital (Schelling, 1992, 1997; Tol, 2005; IPCC, 2012).
Finally, adaptation efforts may reduce adaptation deficits regarding
vulnerability to existing climate and enhance general development
(Burton, 2004). Thus, development goals can be generally consistent
with adaptation goals, with one possibly being an ancillary effect of
the other, although this is not always the case. For example, Hansone
et al. (2001) find that urbanization of flood-prone areas increases
vulnerability and adaptation needs while Burby et al. (2001) and
Hallegatte (2012) indicate better protection may trigger additional
development in at-risk areas and create increased vulnerability to
extreme events.
17.3. Decision Making and
Economic Context for Adaptation
Adaptation will be carried out by multiple public and private actors who
face a number of decision-making barriers that may limit adaptation.
Chapter 16 and many papers (e.g., Fankhauser et al., 1999; Cimato and
Mullan, 2010; Moser and Eckstrom 2010; Biesbroek et al., 2011;
Fankhauser and Soare, 2013) investigate these barriers. This section
Frequently Asked Questions
FAQ 17.1 | Given the significant uncertainty about the effects of adaptation measures, can
economics contribute much to decision making in this area?
Economic methods have been developed to inform a wide range of issues that involve decision making in the face
of uncertainty. Indeed some of these methods have already been applied to the evaluation of adaptation measures,
such as decisions on which coastal areas to protect and how much to protect them.
A range of methods can be applied, depending on the available information and the questions being asked. Where
probabilities can be attached to different outcomes that may result from an adaptation measure, economic tools
such as risk and portfolio theory allow us to choose the adaptation option that maximizes the expected net benefits,
while allowing for the risks associated with different options. Such an approach compares not only the net benefits
of each measure but also the risks associated with it (e.g., the possibility of a very poor outcome).
In situations where probabilities cannot be defined, economic analysis can define scenarios that describe a possible
set of outcomes for each adaptation measure that meet some criteria of minimum acceptable benefits across a
range of scenarios, allowing the decision maker to explore different levels of acceptable benefits in a systematic
way. That, of course, hinges on the definition of “acceptability,” which is a complex matter that accounts for
community values as well as physical outcomes. These approaches can be applied to climate change impacts such
as sea level rise, river flooding, and energy planning.
In some cases it is difficult to place specific economic values on important outcomes (e.g., disasters involving large-
scale loss of life). An alternative to the risk or portfolio theory approach can then be used, that identifies the least-
cost solution that keeps probable losses to an acceptable level.
There are, however, still unanswered questions on how to apply economic methods to this kind of problem
(particularly when the changes caused by climate change are large and when people’s valuations may be changed),
and on how to improve the quality of information on the possible impacts and benefits.
955
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
r
eviews them from an economic perspective, and then turns to the
decision-making frameworks that can help implement adaptation
actions in spite of these barriers.
17.3.1. Economic Barriers to Adaptation Decision Making
1
7.3.1.1. Transaction Costs, Information, and Adjustment Costs
Transaction costs include the costs of accessing markets and information,
along with reaching an agreement and enforcement costs (Coase, 1937,
1960; Williamson, 1979). Because of transaction costs, a beneficial
adaptation action may be undesirable. Two specific types of transaction
costs are those relating to information and those relating to adjustment.
Information acquisition costs can represent a significant obstacle, for
instance, when climate and weather data are costly or difficult to access
(e.g., Cimato and Mullan, 2010; Ford et al., 2011; Scott et al., 2011).
Because information is a public good, private actors tend to under-
provide it and there is a role for government and public authorities to
support its production and dissemination (e.g., through research funding,
observation networks, or information distribution systems; Fankhauser
et al., 1999; Mendelsohn, 2000; Trenberth, 2008).
Adjustment costs represent another barrier, especially in the presence
of uncertainty and learning, and when long-lived capital is concerned.
Fankhauser et al. (1999) discuss adjustment costs as a barrier to early
capital replacement to adapt to a different climate. Kelly and Kolstad
(2005) define adjustment costs as the cost incurred while learning about
new climate conditions. Using these different definitions, these analyses
suggest that adjustment costs can represent a significant share of
adaptation costs.
17.3.1.2. Market Failures and Missing Markets
Adaptation may also face market failures such as externalities,
information asymmetry, and moral hazards (see Section 17.2.1;
Osberghaus et al., 2010a). As a consequence, some socially desirable
actions may not be privately profitable. For example, flood mitigation
measures may not be implemented in spite of their benefits, when flood
risks are partly assumed by insurance or post-disaster support,
transferring risk to the community (a case of moral hazard; Burby et al.,
1991; Laffont, 1995). There are also externalities, as adaptation actions
by one household, firm, or even country may create higher damages for
others. This is the case with transboundary waters, when increased
irrigation in one country creates water scarcity downstream (Goulden
et al., 2009). Trans-sector effects can also take place, for instance when
adaptation in one sector creates needs in another sector (e.g., the
impact on transportation of agriculture adaptation; see Attavanich et
al., 2013). Incentives for private adaptation actions may also be lacking
for public goods and common resources without property rights (e.g.,
biodiversity and natural areas, tradition, and culture). And adaptation
may exhibit increasing returns or large fixed costs, leading to insufficient
adaptation investments (e.g., Eisenack, 2013). In such contexts, public
norms and standards, direct public investment, tax measures, or national
o
r international institutions for adaptation coordination are needed to
avoid maladaptation.
17.3.1.3. Behavioral Obstacles to Adaptation
Economic agents adapt continuously to climate conditions, though not
always using the available information, especially long-term projections
of consequences (Camerer and Kunreuther, 1989; Thaler, 1999; Michel-
Kerjan, 2006). Individuals often defer choosing between ambiguous
choices (Tversky and Shafir, 1992; Trope and Lieberman, 2003) and make
decisions that are time inconsistent (e.g., they attribute a lower weight
to the long term through “hyperbolic discounting”; see Ainslie, 1975).
They also systematically favor the status quo and familiar choices
(Johnson and Goldstein, 2003). Also, individuals value profits and losses
differently (Tversky and Kahnman, 1974). Behavioral issues may lead
to suboptimal adaptation decisions, as illustrated with case studies in
Germany and Zimbabwe in Grothmann and Patt (2005). Particularly
important is the fact that the provision of climate information needs to
account for cognitive failures (Suarez and Patt, 2004; Osberghaus et al.,
2010b). Individual behavioral barriers extend to cultural factors and
social norms, which can support or impair adaptation as illustrated by
Nielsen and Reenberg (2010) in Burkina Faso.
17.3.1.4. Ethics and Distributional Issues
A difficulty in allocating adaptation resources noted in Section 17.2.3
is the limitation of indicators based on costs and benefits (Adger et al.,
2005; Füssel, 2010). Outcomes are often measured using such methods
but their limits are well known, (e.g., CMEPSP, 2009; OECD, 2009; Heal,
2012) and include the failure to take into account resource depletion,
environmental change, and distributional issues.
Distributional issues may justify public intervention based on ethics and
values. Climate change impacts vary greatly by social group, and many
have suggested that the poor are particularly vulnerable (e.g., Stern,
2006; Füssel et al., 2012). Some individuals, firms, communities, and
even countries may be unable to afford adaptation, even if it is in their
own interest. Also, individuals with different world views or preferences
(e.g., regarding risk aversion; see Adger et al., 2009) may ask for different
adaptation measures and have different views of what is an acceptable
level of residual risk (Peters and Slovic, 1996). Consideration of justice
and fairness will play a role in adaptation option design (Adger et al.,
2006; Brauch, 2009a,b; Dalby, 2009; O’Brien et al., 2009, 2010; Pelling
and Dill, 2009). The implementation of adaptation options may thus
require taking into account the political economy of reforms and the
need to compensate losers (World Bank, 2012).
The traditional economic approach suggests choosing the most cost-
effective projects and then resorting to financial transfers to satisfy
equity objectives (Atkinson and Stiglitz, 1976; Brown and Heal, 1979).
However, this embodies strong assumptions including the ability to
realize perfect and costless financial transfers. In more realistic
situations the choice is not so clear cut. In practical terms, transfers are
difficult to organize and may not be politically acceptable (Kanbur, 2010).
956
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
I
n these cases, adaptation decision making needs to account for both
the net benefits and the impacts on equity (Aakre and Rübbelke, 2010).
17.3.1.5 Coordination, Government Failures,
and Political Economy
One of the main roles of governments and local authorities is to remove
barriers—realigning the incentives of individuals with the goals of
society, providing the public goods needed for adaptation, or helping
with behavioral and cognitive biases. But governments and local
authorities face their own barriers, often referred to as government or
regulatory failures (Krueger, 1990). First, government and local authority
decision makers, as individuals, face their own barriers, such a cognitive
and behavioral biases (Podsakoff et al., 1990). Public decision makers
are also confronted with moral hazard, for instance, when subnational
entities are provided support from the government in case of disaster
(Michel-Kerjan, 2006). Second, governments may have access to
insufficient resources or limited adaptation capacity, especially in
poorer countries and where governments have limited access to capital
markets and are unable to fund projects, even when they are cost
efficient (e.g., Brooks et al., 2005; Smit and Wandel, 2006; World Bank,
2012). There can also be coordination failures within the government,
as many adaptation options require multi-ministry actions (e.g., the
reduction of flood risks may require some prevention measure
implemented by the environmental ministry and an insurance scheme
regulated by the ministry of finance; World Bank, 2013).
Other government failures can arise. Frequently government action is
driven by narrow interest groups and is not in the public interest (Levine
and Forrence, 1990; James, 2000). Multi-stakeholder approaches have
been shown to help address these problems, with a relevant example
for this context being coral reef management in Tobago (Adger et al.,
2005).
17.3.1.6. Uncertainty
Decisions about adaptation have to be made in the face of uncertainty
on items ranging from demography and technology to economic futures.
Climate change adds additional sources of uncertainty, including
uncertainty about the extent and patterns of future climate change (see
the WGI contribution to the AR5), which is dependent on uncertain
socioeconomic development pathways and climate policies (see the
WGIII contribution to the AR5), and uncertainty about the reaction and
adaptation of ecosystems (see Chapters 3 to 13).
Patt and Schröter (2008) show in a case study in Mozambique that
major uncertainties are a strong barrier to successful adaptation.
Uncertainty, coupled with the long lifespan of a number of options, can
lead to “maladaptation, that is, an adaptation action that leads to
increased vulnerability. An “avoidable maladaptation arises from a
poorex ante choice, where available information is not used properly.
An unavoidable ex post maladaptation can result from entirely
appropriate decisions based on the information that was the best
availableat the time of decision making, but subsequently proves to
have been wrong. An example of the latter is a precautionary restriction
p
rohibiting new construction in areas potentially at risk of sea level rise.
Applying such a precautionary approach makes sense when (1) decisions
are at least partly irreversible (e.g., building in flood-prone areas cannot
easily be “un-built”) and (2) the cost of a worst-case scenario is very
high. Such a precautionary measure can make economic senseex ante,
even if sea level rise eventually remains in the lower range of possible
outcomes, making the construction restriction unnecessary.
17.3.2. Economic Decision Making with Uncertainty
Decision making under uncertainty is a central question for climate
change policy and is discussed in many chapters of the AR5, especially in
Chapter 2 and WGIII AR5 Chapters 2 and 3. This section focuses on the
economic approaches to decision making under uncertainty, including
decision-making techniques, valuation tools, and multi-metric decision
making.
17.3.2.1. Cost-Benefit Analysis and Related Methods
There are different tools for decision making that can be applied in
different contexts and with different information. Cost-benefit analysis
under uncertainty applied to adaptation uses subjective probabilities
for different climate futures (e.g., Tebaldi et al., 2005; New and Hulme,
2006; see also Chapter 2). The “best” project is the one that maximizes
the expected net present value of costs and benefits. Risk aversion can
be taken into account through (nonlinear) welfare functions or the
explicit introduction of a risk premium.
When conducting cost-benefit analyses under uncertainty, an important
question is the timing of action, that is, the possibility of delaying a
decision until more information is available (e.g., Fankhauser and Soare,
2013). Real option techniques are an extension of cost-benefit analysis
to capture this possibility and balance the costs and benefits of delaying
a decision (Arrow and Fisher, 1974; Henry, 1974). The benefits depend
on how much learning can take place over time. A key issue concerns
irreversible actions, such as the destruction of a unique environment
(Heal and Kristrom, 2003).
Application of cost-benefit or real option analysis requires evaluations
in monetary terms. For market impacts, prices may need to be corrected
for policies, monopoly power, or other external factors distorting market
prices (Squire and van der Tak, 1975). But a cost-benefit analysis also
often requires the valuation of non-market costs and benefits. This is
the case for impacts on public health, cultural heritage, environmental
quality and ecosystems, and distributional impacts. Valuation of non-
market impact is difficult because of values and preferences heterogeneity,
and subject to controversies—for example, on the value to attribute to
avoided death (see Viscusi and Aldy, 2003).
There has been progress in valuation of ecosystem services, as elaborated
in the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MEA, 2005), The Economics
of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB, 2010), and Bateman et al. (2011).
Two main categories of approaches have been developed: revealed and
stated preference methods. The latter is based on what people say about
their preferences, while the former uses their actual decisions (e.g., how
957
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
m
uch they pay for a house) and is often considered more accurate. Other
approaches include avoided or replacement cost, that is, measuring the
cost of providing the ecosystem service artificially. When local information
is not available, value transfer techniques can be applied moving
information from other locations. For example, Brander et al. (2012)
applies value transfer to climate change impacts on wetlands but
caution is required in making such transfers (National Research Council,
2005; Navrud and Ready, 2007).
Theoretically, cost-benefit approaches can account for distributional
impacts, for instance, through attribution of a higher weight to the poorest
(Harberger, 1984). Results are however highly dependent on preferences
that can be extremely heterogeneous and difficult to measure (Barsky
et al., 1997). As discussed in detail in Chapter 2, valuation and decision
making cannot be separated from the institutional and social contexts
(e.g., what is considered as a right). Yet, overall, as concluded by the IPCC
Special Report on Managing the Risks of Extreme Events and Disasters
to Advance Climate Change Adaptation (SREX), the applicability of
rigorous community-based adaptations (CBAs) for evaluations of
adaptation to climate variability and change may be limited (Handmer
et al., 2012).
17.3.2.2. Multi-Metric Decision Making for Adaptation
Multi-metric decision making provides a broader framework, which also
permits balancing among multiple, potentially competing objectives
(Keeney and Raiffa, 1993). This branch of decision analysis is also known
as multi-criterion analysis. Such an approach is helpful when decision
makers have difficulty in trading off different objectives (Martinez-Alier
et al., 1998). Using multiple criteria, decision makers can include a full
range of social, environmental, technical, and economic criteria—mainly
by quantifying and displaying trade-offs. Multi-criterion analyses have
been applied to adaptation issues including urban flood risk (Kubal et
al., 2009; Grafakos, 2012; Viguie and Hallegatte, 2012), agricultural
vulnerability (Julius and Scheraga, 2000), and choice of adaptation
options in the Netherlands (Brouwer and van Ek, 2004; de Bruin et al.,
2009a), Canada (Qin et al., 2008), and Africa (Smith and Lenhart, 1996).
The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC)
developed guidelines for the adaptation assessment process in developing
countries in which it suggests the use of multi-criteria analysis (UNFCCC,
2002). As an illustration, Figure 17-3 shows a multi-criteria analysis of
three urban policies in the Paris agglomeration, using five policy objectives
and success indicators (climate change mitigation, adaptation and
risk management, natural area and biodiversity protection, housing
affordability, and policy neutrality).
17.3.2.3. Non-Probabilistic Methodologies
Cost-benefit analysis and related methods require probabilities for each
climate scenario. But in most cases, it may be impossible to define (or
to agree on) probabilities for alternative outcomes, or even to identify
the set of possible futures (including highly improbable events) (Henry
and Henry, 2002; Gilboa, 2010; Millner et al., 2010; Kunreuther et al.,
2012). This is especially true for low-probability, high-impact cases or
poorly understood risks (Weitzman, 2009; Kunreuther et al., 2012). In
such contexts, various approaches have been proposed (see reviews in
Ranger et al., 2010; Hallegatte et al., 2012; see also Chapter 2).
Scenario-based analyses study different policies in different scenarios
that try and cover the uncertainty space for key parameters (Schwartz,
1996). This is the approach followed by many climate change impact and
adaptation studies when using several IPCC Special Report on Emission
Scenarios (SRES) scenarios (Carter et al., 2001, 2007; Hallegatte et al.,
2011). Then, various methodologies or criteria can be used to make a
decision.
The maxi–min criterion suggests choosing the decision with the best
worst-case outcome and the mini–max regret criterion (Savage, 1951)
suggests choosing the decision with the smallest deviation from optimality
in any state of the world. Proposals for “no regrets” adaptation decisions
(Callaway and Hellmuth, 2007; Heltberg et al., 2009) employ such criteria.
Hybrid criteria balance between optimal and worst case performance
(Hurwicz, 1951; Aaheim and Bretteville, 2001; Froyn, 2005).
Another criterion is based on “robustness” and seeks decisions that
will perform well over a wide range of plausible climate futures,
socioeconomic trends, and other factors (Lempert and Schlesinger, 2000;
Lempert et al., 2006; Dessai and Hulme, 2007; Lempert and Collins,
2007; Groves et al., 2008; Wilby and Dessai, 2010; WUCA, 2010; Brown
et al., 2011; Lempert and Kalra, 2011). Instead of starting from a few
scenarios, these methods start with an option or a project and test it
under a large number of scenarios to identify its vulnerabilities to
uncertain parameters. Small adjustment or large changes in options or
projects can then be identified to minimize these vulnerabilities. Example
implementations include InfoGap, which has been used to inform
958
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
a
daptation decisions in water management (Ben-Haim, 2001; Korteling
et al., 2013); RDM (robust decision making), which has been used for
water management and flood risk management planning (Lempert et al.,
2003; Lempert and Groves, 2010; Lempert and Kalra, 2011; Matrosov et
al., 2013); and robust control optimization (Hansen and Sargent, 2008).
Figure 17-4 illustrates the application of robust decision making on
flood risks in Ho Chi Minh City (Lempert et al., 2013). The analysis
examined different risk management portfolios (including, for instance,
raising homes and retreat). Each portfolio was simulated in 1000
scenarios, covering socioeconomic and climate uncertainty. The RDM
analysis found that the current plan is robust to a wide range of possible
future population and economic trends. But it would keep risk below
current levels only if rainfall intensities increase by no more than 5%
and if the Saigon River rises less than 45 cm. Additional measures were
found that made the situation robust for increases in rainfall intensity of
up to 35% and increases in the level of the Saigon River of up to 100 cm.
17.4. Costing Adaptation
Interest in estimating the costs of adaptation has grown as the need
for action has become clearer. The literature focuses on two levels of
costing: global scale estimates, largely to assess the overall need for
adaptation finance funds; and regional and local-scale estimates, often
limited to a particular vulnerable economic sector, which may be applied
to inform budgeting or to support adaptation decision making, or
to allocate scarce resources among the best prospects for effective
a
daptation. The methods for these two types of studies vary widely, but
for the important methodological considerations for costing adaptation
are similar for both types.
17.4.1. Methodological Considerations
1
7.4.1.1. Data Quality and Quantity
There is very little discussion of data gaps related to assessing the
benefits of adaptation, but poor or sparse data obviously limit the
accuracy of these estimates. Callaway (2004) suggests that a major
challenge is the low quality and limited nature of data, especially in many
developing countries, and notes many transactions are not reported
because they occur in informal economies and social networks. In a more
general setting Hughes et al. (2010) note that historical weather data
are not typically sufficiently detailed while others note sparse data on
costs of adaptation actions. For example, Bjarnadottie et al. (2011) note
incomplete and contradictory data on house retrofit costs for hurricane
protection. Also there are simply missing non-market data on such items
as the value of ecosystem services (Agrawala and Fankhauser, 2008),
particularly as affected by climate and possible adaptation.
17.4.1.2. Costs and Benefits Are Location-Specific
Calculating localized impacts requires detailed geographical knowledge
of climate change impacts, but these are a major source of uncertainty
Rainwater
(10%,100 cm)
Relocate
(17%,100 cm)
All options
(32%,100 cm)
Elevate and relocate with adaptive
groundwater and rainwater
(26%, 100 cm)
Elevate and relocate
(21%, 85 cm)
Groundwater and
rainwater with adaptive
elevate and relocate
(17%, 100 cm)
Groundwater and
rainwater
(17%, 100 cm)
NOAA SLR estimate with
continued subsidence (75 cm)
Groundwater
(7%,55 cm)
Baseline
(6%,55 cm)
Elevate
(23%,55 cm)
MONRE SLR estimate (30 cm)
IPCC SREX
mid value (20%)
IPCC SREX
high value (35%)
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
0
0% 5% 10% 10% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 55% 60%
Percent increase in rainfall intensity
Increase in Saigon River levels (cm)
Figure 17-4 | Various risk management strategies in Ho Chi Minh City, and their robustness to increases in river levels and rainfall intensity. Different options can cope with
different amplitudes of environmental change (Lempert et al., 2013).
959
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
in climate models (see Refsgaard et al., 2013). Global estimates of
adaptation cost are generally not grounded in local-scale physical
attributes important for adaptation, which in part explains why local
and regional-scale adaptation cost estimates are not consistent with
global estimates (Agrawala and Fankhauser, 2008). Compared with
developed countries, there is also a limited understanding of the potential
market sector impacts of climate change in developing countries.
17.4.1.3. Costs and Benefits Depend on Socioeconomics
It is sometimes assumed that climate will change but society will not
(Pielke, 2007; Hallegatte et al., 2011; Mechler and Bouwer, 2013). Future
development paths affect climate change impact estimates, and can alter
estimates from positive to negative impacts or vice versa. Some studies
show higher growth rates raise hurricane vulnerability (Bjarnadottir,
2011). On the other hand, higher incomes allow the funding of risk-
reducing policies.
17.4.1.4. Discount Rates Matter
Because adaptation costs and consequences occur over time, discount
rates are a core question. Opinions vary sharply on this question (Baum,
2009; Heal 2009). Hof et al. (2010) notes that a low discount rate is
needed for distant future climate change to matter. A low discount rate
is the primary reason for the relatively high estimates of climate damage
in the Stern Review (Stern, 2006). For climate adaptation projects, the
social or consumption discount rate is the relevant one (Heal, 2009).
The rates used fall between 0.1 and 2.5%, although without good
arguments for specific values (see Heal, 2009). Nordhaus (2008) chooses
a value of 1.5% while Stern uses a much lower value of 0.1%. Nordhaus
emphasizes consistency with the rate of return on investment as a driving
rationale while Stern points to ethical issues. Allowing environmental
services to enter consumption can change the social discount rate
substantially and generate a low or even negative social discount rate
(Guesnerie, 2004; Sterner and Persson, 2007; Heal, 2009). The UK
Treasury now mandates the use of declining discount rates for long-
term projects, as suggested by behavioral studies and by theoretical
analysis (Arrow et al., 2012).
17.4.2. Review of Existing Global Estimates:
Gaps and Limitations
There has been a limited number of global and regional adaptation cost
assessments over the last few years (Stern, 2006; World Bank, 2006,
2010a; Oxfam, 2007; UNDP, 2007; UNFCCC, 2007, 2008). These estimates
exhibit a large range and have been completed mostly for developing
countries. The most recent and most comprehensive to date global
adaptation costs range from US$70 to more than US$100 billion annually
by 2050 (World Bank, 2010a; see Table 17-2).
IPCC (2012) considers confidence in these numbers to be low because
the estimates are derived from only three relatively independent lines
of evidence. World Bank (2006) estimates the cost of climate proofing
foreign direct investments (FDI), gross domestic investments (GDI), and
Official Development Assistance (ODA), as does the Stern Review (2006),
Oxfam (2007), and UNDP (2007). UNFCCC (2007) calculated existing and
planned investment and financial flows (I&FF), and then estimated the
additional investment required for adaptation as a premium on existing
and planned investments. The World Bank (2010a) followed the UNFCCC
(2007) methodology of estimating the premium climate change imposes
on a baseline of existing and planned investment, but included more
extensive modeling (as opposed to developing unit cost estimates),
constructed marginal cost curves and climate stressor-response functions
for adaptation actions, and included maintenance and coastal port
upgrading costs.
Given their common approaches these estimates are interlinked, which
explains the seeming convergence of their estimates in later years, as
discussed by Parry et al. (2009). However, there are important differences
in terms of sectoral estimates, as Figure 17-5 shows in comparing the
UNFCCC (2007) and World Bank (2010a) studies. Extreme events, a
potential source of large adaptation costs, are not properly covered,
and these studies take into account a limited set of adaptation options.
In addition, the World Bank (2010a) estimates report higher ranges of
estimates, reflecting additional effort to account for uncertainty. Parry
et al. (2009) consider the UNFCCC (2007) estimates a significant
underestimation by at least a factor of two to three plus omitted costs
in ecosystem services, energy, manufacturing, retailing, and tourism.
Thus the numbers have to be treated with caution. There are a number
Study
Results
(billion US$
per year)
Time frame Sectors Methodology and comments
World Bank
(2006)
9 41 Present Unspecifi ed Cost of climate proofi ng foreign direct investments, gross domestic investments,
and Offi cial Development Assistance
Stern (2007) 4 37 Present Unspecifi ed Update of World Bank (2006)
Oxfam (2007) >50 Present Unspecifi ed World Bank (2006) plus extrapolation of cost estimates from national
adaptation plans and NGO projects
UNDP (2007) 86 109 2015 Unspecifi ed World Bank (2006) plus costing of targets for adapting poverty reduction
programs and strengthening disaster response systems
UNFCCC
(2007)
28 67 2030 Agriculture, forestry and fi sheries; water supply; human
health; coastal zones; infrastructure
Planned investment and fi nancial fl ows required for the international
community
World Bank
(2010a)
70 100 2050 Agriculture, forestry and fi sheries; water supply; human
health; coastal zones; infrastructure; extreme events
Improvement on UNFCCC (2007): more precise unit cost, inclusion of cost of
maintenance and port upgrading, risks from sea level rise and storm surges
Table 17-2 | Estimates of global costs of adaptation.
Source: Modifi ed from Agrawala and Fankhauser (2008) and Parry et al. (2009) to include estimates from World Bank (2010a).
960
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
of gaps, challenges, and omissions associated with those global estimates
that merit further discussion.
The practical challenges of conducting global adaptation cost studies are
apparent in the literature (as assessed in Parry et al., 2009; World Bank,
2010a; IPCC, 2012). The broad scope of these studies limits the analysis
to few climate scenarios, and while the scenarios might be strategically
chosen it is difficult to represent fully the range of future adaptation
costs across all sectors. The broad scope also limits comprehensive
consideration of adaptation options, non-market and co-benefits, equity
issues, and adaptation decision making (such limitations also apply to
local and regional scale studies; see Section 17.4.3). The global studies,
designed to reflect the best available methods and data for the purpose
of estimating the magnitude of the global economic adaptation challenge,
achieve this limited goal but must be interpreted in light of these
important limitations and uncertainties.
17.4.3. Consistency between Localized and Global Analyses
Adaptation costs and benefits are derived to guide specific investment
decisions, generally at national and local levels, or to derive a “price tag
for overall funding needs for adaptation (generally at a global level).
Given these different purposes it is difficult to compare “local,” that is,
national and sectoral, with global numbers. The quantity/quality of local
studies also varies by sector with more treatment of adaptation in
coastal zones and agriculture (Agrawala and Fankhauser, 2008; see
Table 17-3). Less is known and many gaps remain for sectors such as
water resources, energy, ecosystems, infrastructure, tourism, and public
h
ealth. Also assessments have predominantly been conducted in a
developed country context (see Table 17-1 for examples of costs and
benefits assessment).
However, as Fankhauser (2010) notes, with the sole exception of coastal
protection costs, adaptation costs have shown little convergence locally
or in terms of sectoral to global costs. The World Bank (2010a) study
uniquely takes a two-track approach doing parallel national (seven
cases) and global adaptation estimates. For a number of country studies
(Bangladesh, Samoa, and Vietnam) a cross-country comparison of local
and global adaptation costs was made, with the costs in terms of gross
domestic product (GDP) found to be in reasonable agreement. Costs
for strengthening infrastructure against windstorms, precipitation, and
flooding were about 10 to 20% higher compared to disaggregated
global estimates, largely owing to the ability of country-level studies to
consider at least some socially contingent impacts (World Bank,
2010a,b,c,d). Further, there is evidence of under-investment in adaptation
(UNDP, 2007), with global estimates of the need for adaptation funds
variously estimated in the range of US$70 to US$100 billion annually
(World Bank, 2010a), but with actual expenditures in 2011 estimated at
US$244 million (Elbehri et al, 2011), and in 2012 estimated at US$395
million (Schalatek et al., 2012).
17.4.4. Selected Studies on Sectors or Regions
This section focuses on studies that illustrate current practice in estimating
adaptation economics, with a particular focus on support of adaptation
decision making through economic analysis. Within that class of work,
there are two broad categories of economic analyses of adaptation at
the sectoral level: econometric and simulation approaches.
Econometric studies generally examine the nature of observed adaptations
or the estimation of climate change effects to which farmers have adapted.
Such studies rely on observed cross-sectional, time series, or panel data.
Examples include those where one implicitly assumes adaptation has
occurred linking temperature and precipitation to land values and crop
yields or land values (e.g., Mendelsohn et al., 1994; Schlenker et al.,
2006) or those identifying adaptations in terms of altered decisions, for
Table 17-3 | Coverage of adaptation costs and benefi ts.
Sector Analytical coverage
Cost
estimates
Benefi t
estimates
Coastal
zones
Comprehensive
✓✓✓ ✓✓✓
Agriculture Comprehensive
✓✓✓
Water Isolated case studies
✓✓
Energy North America, Europe
✓✓ ✓✓
Infrastructure Cross-cutting, partly covered in other sectors
✓✓
Health Selected impacts
Tourism Winter tourism
Note: Three checks indicates good to excellent coverage of the topic in the literature;
two checks indicates medium coverage; one check indicates limited coverage; the
absence of a check indicates extremely limited or no coverage. Note that indicators
refl ect literature review through publication of source in 2008.
Source: Agrawala and Fankhauser (2008).
961
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
example, Seo and Mendelsohn (2008a,c) look at enterprise choice, while
Mu et al. (2013) look at stocking rate adjustments. Such approaches
can also be used to estimate the marginal effect of adaptation, provided
that “without adaptation” estimates can be developed (Mendelsohn
and Dinar, 2003).
The simulation approach, by contrast, traces costs and benefits of
adaptation strategies through mechanisms of interest, typically through a
series of climate-biophysical-behavioral response-economic components.
Within simulation modeling there are two main threads in the behavioral
response-economic component of the simulation. The first involves
rational actors who consider the benefit and cost consequences of their
choices and pursue economically efficient adaptation outcomes, and
the second involves a decision-rule or reference-based characterization
of the response of actors to climate stressors (Schlenker et al., 2006;
Dinar and Mendelsohn, 2011). As noted later, in many sectors the
current practice begins with the simpler decision-rule based approach,
and may progress to consider benefits and costs, and then perhaps to
consider other factors, such as equity and non-market values.
The key advantages of an econometric approach are reliance on real-
world data, the use of “natural experiments” in some cases, and an
ability to reflect the joint costs and benefits of multiple adaptation
strategies to the extent they are employed together in the real world
(Mendelsohn and Neumann, 1999; Dinar and Mendelsohn, 2011). The
econometric approach does not require the analyst to simulate all
adaptation mechanisms, only to establish that there is a robust
relationship between a climate stressor and the outcome of interest. The
data required to implement the approach are limited, so the approach
can be applied broadly. The key disadvantages of the econometric
approach are an inability to trace transmission mechanisms of specific
adaptation measures or to isolate the marginal effect of these strategies
or measures; the inability to transfer estimates out of context (e.g., an
African study does not apply to Asia, where the climate, adaptation,
and social context all differ and affect the marginal costs and benefits
of adaptation measures); and that the statistical estimation can be
challenging and sometimes subject to multiple interpretations (Schlenker
et al., 2005).
Simulation modeling can be demanding—a key disadvantage—as it
requires extensive data inputs and careful calibration. Where data and
models are available, however, the simulation modeling method works
well. For example, an agricultural adaptation modeling system can
estimate such factors as the incremental change in crop output and water
Frequently Asked Questions
FAQ 17.2 | Could economic approaches bias adaptation policy and decisions against
the interests of the poor, vulnerable populations, or ecosystems?
A narrow economic approach can fail to account adequately for such items as ecosystem services and community
value systems, which are sometimes not considered in economic analysis or undervalued by market prices, or for
which data are insufficient. This can bias decisions against the poor, vulnerable populations, or the maintenance
of important ecosystems. For example, the market value of timber neither reflects the ecological and hydrological
functions of trees nor the forest products whose values arise from economic sectors outside the timber industry,
like medicines. Furthermore, some communities value certain assets (historic buildings, religious sites) differently
than others. Broader economic approaches, however, can attach monetary values to non-market impacts, referred
to as externalities, placing an economic value on ecosystem services like breathable air, carbon capture and storage
(in forests and oceans), and usable water. The values for these factors may be less certain than those attached to
market impacts, which can be quantified with market data, but they are still useful to provide economic assessments
that are less biased against ecosystems.
But economic analysis, which focuses on the monetary costs and benefits of an option, is just one important
component of decision making relating to adaptation alternatives, and final decisions about such measures are
almost never based on this information alone. Societal decision making also accounts for equity—who gains and
who loses—and for the impacts of the measures on other factors that are not represented in monetary terms. In
other words, communities make decisions in a larger context, taking into account other socioeconomic and political
factors. What is crucial is that the overall decision framework is broad, with both economic and non-economic factors
being taken into consideration.
A frequently used decision-making framework that provides for the inclusion of economic and non-economic
indicators to measure the impacts of a policy, including impacts on vulnerable groups and ecosystems, is multi-criteria
analysis (MCA). But as with all decision-making approaches, the challenge for MCA and methods like it is the
subjective choices that have to be made about what weights to attach to all the relevant criteria that go into the
analysis, including how the adaptation measure being studied impacts poor or vulnerable populations, or how fair
it is in the distribution of who pays compared to who benefits.
962
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Continued next page
Sector
Study
and scope
Methodology Key points illustrated
Agriculture,
forestry,
and livestock
S
eo and
coinvestigators (e.g.,
S
eo et al., 2008b,
2
009b, 2011): Impacts
to livestock producers
i
n Africa
E
conometric. Examines the economic choices that livestock owners make to
maintain production in the face of climate. Insights into adaption possibilities
a
re achieved by examining the ways economic choices vary over locations and
t
imes with varying climate conditions.
C
onsideration of multiple options (implicit)
Residual impacts refl ected
Applicable at multiple geographic scales
R
esults provide a ready means to re-estimate results for
multiple climate scenarios.
B
utt et al. (2006):
Crop sector in Mali
S
imulation. Simulates the economic implications of potential adaptation
possibilities. Examines the consequences of migration in cropping patterns,
d
evelopment of heat resistant cultivars, reduction in soil productivity loss,
c
ropland expansion, and changes in trade patterns.
B
road consideration of options (explicit, allowing for ranking
of measures)
R
esidual impacts refl ected
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options and
c
onsequences for yields, revenue, and food security
Sutton et al. (2013):
C
rop and livestock
sector in four eastern
European and central
A
sian countries
Simulation with benefi t /cost analysis. Ranks options initially based on net
e
conomic benefi ts over 2010 2050 period. Considers non-market and socially
contingent effects through stakeholder consultation process.
Broad consideration of options (explicit, measures ranked)
V
ery broad representation of climate scenarios (56 General
Circulation Model–Special Report on Emission Scenarios
c
ombinations)
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options
Integrated analysis of agriculture and irrigation water sectors
Sea level rise
and coastal
systems
N
ichols and Tol
(
2006): Coastal
regions at a global
scale
S
imulation of adaptation through construction of seawalls and levees,
a
doption of beach nourishment to maintain recreational value, and migration
of coastal dwellers from vulnerable areas. The study refl ects an economic
decision rule for most categories and benefi t /cost analysis for a few categories
C
apable of broad representation of sea level rise scenarios
O
ptimization of alternatives considering both the impact of
adaptation and resulting residual impacts
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options
Neumann et al.
(
2010a): Risks of sea
level rise for a portion
o
f the coastal United
States
Simulation of adaptation decision making including seawalls, bulkheads,
e
levation of structures, beach nourishment, and strategic retreat, primarily
using a benefi t /cost framework but with alternatives based on local land use
d
ecision-making rules
Capable of broad representation of sea level rise scenarios
Flexibility to consider both benefi t /cost and rule-based
d
ecision making
Rigorous and dynamic economic costing of adaptation
options
Purvis et al. (2008):
Risks of coastal
ooding in Somerset,
England
Simulation using a probabilistic representation to characterize uncertainty in
future sea level rise and, potentially, other factors that could affect coastal
land use planning and development investment decisions
Considers the impact of both gradual climate change (sea
level rise) and extreme events (the 1-in-200-year recurrence
interval coastal fl ooding event)
Incorporates probabilistic uncertainty analysis
Water
Ward et al. (2010):
Future needs and
costs for municipal
water across the
world, scalable to
national and local
scales
Assesses costs with and without climate change of reaching a water supply
target in 2050. The aggregation level used is the food producing units level,
and storage capacity change, using the secant peak algorithm to determine
the storage yield relationship and the cost of various alternative sources
of water. The authors fi nd that baseline costs exceed adaptation costs ($73
billion per year versus $12 billion per year for adaptation), with most of the
adaptation costs (83 90%) incurred in developing countries.
Multiple climate scenarios
Scalable to multiple spatial resolutions, with national and
regional results reported
Multiple alternative adaptation options considered
Rigorous economic costing of site-specifi c capital and
operating costs
Urban fl ooding
Ranger et al. (2011):
direct and indirect
impacts of fl ooding in
Mumbai, India
Investigates the consequences of fl oods with different return periods, with
and without climate change; the effect of climate change is from a weather
generator that downscales simulations from a global climate model. Estimates
direct losses from a 100-year event rising from $600 million today to $1890
million in the 2080s, and total losses (including indirect losses) rising from
$700 to $2435 million. Impacts give rise to adaptation options, some targeting
direct losses (e.g., improved building quality, improved drainage infrastructure)
and others targeting indirect losses (e.g., increased reconstruction capacity,
micro-insurance). Analysis fi nds that improved housing quality and drainage
could bring total losses in the 2080s below current levels and that full access
to insurance would halve indirect losses for large events.
Considers multiple adaptation options
Explicitly considers both direct and indirect costs
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options
Energy
Lucena et al. (2010):
Energy production
in Brazil, particularly
from hydropower
Simulation of multiple adaptation options, including energy source
substitution and regional “wheeling” of power coupled with modeling of river
ow and hydropower production under future climatic conditions. Uses an
optimization model of overall energy production.
Considers two greenhouse gas emissions scenarios and a
“no-climate change” baseline
Scalable to multiple spatial resolutions, with national and
regional results reported
Considers multiple adaptation strategies
Rigorous economic costing of capital and recurring
adaptation costs
Health
Ebi (2008): Global
adaptation costs of
treatment of diarrheal
diseases, malnutrition,
and malaria
The costs of three diseases were estimated in 2030 for three climate scenarios
using (1) the current numbers of cases; (2) the projected relative risks of these
diseases in 2030; and (3) current treatment costs. The analysis assumed that
the costs of treatment would remain constant. There was limited consideration
of socioeconomic development.
Multiple climate scenarios
Clear description of framework and key assumptions
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options using
multiple assumptions to characterize uncertainty
Table 17-4 | Studies illustrating economic evaluation of adaptation options.
963
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
supply in response to changes in climatic conditions and agricultural and
water resource management techniques. A further advantage of the
simulation approach is that it provides an opportunity for stakeholder
involvement at several stages of the analytic process: designing
scope, adjusting parameters, selecting inputs, calibrating results, and
incorporating adaptation measures of specific local interest (Dinar and
Mendelsohn, 2011).
A wide range of studies attempt an economic evaluation of adaptation
options. From these, several desirable characteristics can be identified:
A broad representation of climate stressors, including both gradual
change and extreme events, spanning multiple future outcomes
(e.g., a range of individual climate model forecasts and greenhouse
gas emissions scenarios). Consideration of multiple outcomes reflects
forecasting uncertainty and can help to ensure the adaptation
rankings that result from the analysis are robust across a range of
future outcomes (Lempert and Kalra, 2009; Agrawala et al., 2011;
see also Chapter 2).
Representation of a wide variety of alternative adaptation responses
(e.g., in the agriculture sector, consideration of changes in crop
varieties and farmer education to ensure the varieties are grown with
the best available know-how). Depending on the context, single
adaptation response with variation in dimension may be useful
(e.g., varying the height of a levee or the capacity of a dam spillway)
(Fankhauser et al., 1999; Fankhauser, 2010; World Bank, 2010a).
Rigorous economic analysis of costs and benefits, which ideally
includes consideration of market, non-market, and socially contingent
implications (Watkiss, 2011); one-time and replacement capital and
ongoing recurring costs; and costs of residual damages after an
adaptation response is implemented (World Bank, 2010a).
A strong focus on adaptation decision making, including a clear
exposition of the form of adaptation decision making that is implied
in the study, and consideration of both climate and non-climate
sources of uncertainty (Lempert et al., 2006; see also Chapter 2).
Table 17-4 highlights studies that illustrate some of these characteristics.
The studies include both simulation studies of the economic implications
of adaptation options, and econometric ones that examine choices that
producers make to adapt. These studies generally fall in the category
of positive economics, where economic tools and analysis are used to
examine the implications of alternative choices without imposing values
of the author (see Friedman, 1953). A few studies incorporate a normative
perspective, either explicitly or implicitly, reflecting value judgments of
authors or study participants.
17.5. Economic and Related Instruments
to Provide Incentives
Through regulations, subsidies, and direct intervention, there are many
opportunities for policymakers to encourage autonomous adaptation.
However, these efforts need to be designed so as to yield efficient, cost-
effective responses while avoiding perverse results. A basic issue of
designing efficient policies is to understand that they affect the behavior
of those who have the most to gain. For this and other reasons,
economists tend to favor policies based on voluntary actions influenced
by incentives, either positive or negative, over mandates or uniform
policies. Examples of these include insurance markets, water markets,
and various payments for environmental services (PES) schemes. A
second consideration in policy design is cost effectiveness, that is, the
extent to which governments make the best use of their resources. The
measurement of the net effect of a policy is challenging because it is
difficult to anticipate what would have occurred without the policy.
Finally, policies must be carefully designed to avoid perverse outcomes
that run counter to the policymaker’s objectives. A classic example is
found in policies that encourage adoption of water-saving technology.
Pfeiffer and Lin (2010) review cases where subsidizing irrigation water
conservation leads farmers to increase total water use by increasing the
acreage under irrigation. This is an example of what is often called the
rebound effect (Roy, 2000), whereby increases in efficiency of resource
use result in more being demanded.
With the exception of insurance- and trade-related instruments there
is relatively little literature on the use of economic instruments for
adaptation (see Chapter 10). One reason is that, apart from insurance, few
adaptation policies work directly via economic incentives and markets. The
potential of economic instruments in an adaptation context is, however,
Sector
Study
and scope
Methodology Key points illustrated
Macroeconomic
analysis
D
e Bruin et al.
(2009b): Adaptation
s
trategies compared
to mitigation
s
trategies within
the context of a
g
lobal integrated
a
ssessment model
U
se of an integrated assessment model (the DICE model) with refi ned
adaptation functions. Examines the effi cacy of “stock” adaptations (mainly
i
nfrastructure) adaptations versus “fl ow” adaptations (mainly operational or
market responses), with comparisons to mitigation investments.
M
ultiple climate scenarios
C
lear description of framework and key assumptions
Considers multiple adaptation strategies
Rigorous economic costing of adaptation options
Margulis et al. (2011):
C
limate change
impacts in the
e
conomy
Use of a general equilibrium model to simulate two climate change-free
s
cenarios regarding the future of Brazil’s economy. Climate shocks were
projected and captured by the model through impacts on the agricultural /
l
ivestock and energy sectors. The socioeconomic trends of the scenarios with
and without global climate change were reviewed in terms of benefi ts and
costs for Brazil and its regions.
The economic impacts of climate change are experienced
a
cross business sectors, regions, states, and large cities and
were expressed in terms of gross domestic product losses.
T
he simulation disaggregates results for up to 55 sectors
and 110 products and also provides macroeconomic
p
rojections such as infl ation, exchange rate, household
sector consumption, government expenditures, aggregate
i
nvestment, and exports. It also includes expert projections
and scenarios on specifi c preferences, technology, and sector
policies.
Table 17-4 (continued)
964
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
widely recognized. In line with Agrawala and Fankhauser (2008), we
distinguish, among others, the following incentive-providing instruments
relevant for key sectors: (1) insurance schemes (all sectors; extreme
events); (2) price signals/markets (water, ecosystems); (3) regulatory
measures and incentives (building standards, zone planning); and (4)
research and development incentives (agriculture, health).
17.5.1. Risk Sharing and Risk Transfer, Including Insurance
Insurance-related formal and informal mechanisms can directly lead to
adaptation and provide incentives or disincentives. Informal mechanisms
include reliance on national or international aid or remittances, and
though such mechanisms are common, they tend to break down for
large, covariate events (Cohen and Sebstad, 2005). Another informal
mechanism is the inclusion of climate change risk under corporate
disclosure regulations (National Round Table on the Environment and
the Economy, 2012). Formal mechanisms include insurance, micro-
insurance, reinsurance, and risk pooling arrangements. Insurance typically
involves ongoing premium payments in exchange for coverage and post
event claim payments. In contrast to indemnity-based insurance, index-
based insurance insures the event (as, e.g., measured by lack of rainfall),
not the loss, and is a possibility for providing a safety net without moral
hazard, yet suffers from basis risk, the lack of correlation of loss to event
(Collier et al. 2009; Hochrainer et al., 2009; see also Section 10.7 for a
supply-side-focused perspective on insurance). Markets differ substantially
according to how liability and responsibility is distributed (Aakre et al.,
2009; Botzen et al., 2009), and in many instances governments play a
key role as regulators, insurers, or reinsurers (Linnerooth-Bayer et al.,
2005). Insurance penetration in developed countries is considerable,
whereas it is low in many developing regions. In the period 1980–2004
about 30% of losses were insured in high-income countries, but only
about 1% in low-income countries (Linnerooth-Bayer et al., 2011).
Developing countries are beginning to pool risks and transfer portions
to international reinsurance markets. The Caribbean Catastrophic Risk
Insurance Facility (CCRIF) set the precedent by pooling risks basin wide,
thus reducing insurance premiums against hurricane and earthquake risks
(World Bank, 2007). Similar schemes are under development planning in
Europe, Africa, and the Pacific (Linerooth-Bayer et al., 2011).
Insurance-related instruments may promote adaptation directly and
indirectly: (1) Instruments provide claim payments after an event, and
thus reduce follow-on risk and consequences; and (2) they alleviate
certain pre-event risks and allow for improved decisions (Hess and
Syroka, 2005; Hoppe and Gurenko, 2006; Skees et al., 2008). As one
interesting example, using crop micro-insurance linked to loans, farmers
exposed to severe drought in Malawi were able to grow higher-yield, yet
higher-risk crops, which allowed them to increase incomes (Linnerooth-
Bayer and Mechler, 2011).
The indirect effects occur via the provision of incentives and disincentives.
Premiums for risk coverage can provide an incentive to reduce the
premium by reducing the risk. In practice, the incentive effect is generally
weak. Kunreuther et al. (2009) found that insurance decisions are not
based solely on costs and premiums, but also desires to reduce anxiety,
comply with mortgage requirements, and satisfy social norms. Further,
purchasing insurance may reduce adaptation with insured agents
reducing their risk-minimizing efforts after taking out coverage. This is
termed moral hazard and has been found to be rational (Kunreuther,
1
998). Moral hazard can be reduced through the use of index-based
insurance, although this has the drawback of operating from a high
base risk (Collier et al., 2009; Hochrainer et al., 2009). Another difficulty
arises when local or state regulations undermine incentives to decrease
risk (for instance, by not allowing insurance rates to be fully risk adjusted).
Some analysts suggest the removal of existing regulations that distort
market signals in order to re-align incentives, yet this is likely to be
ineffective given that the incentive effect is not considered very strong and
often premiums are not fully risk-based (Michel-Kerjan and Kunreuther,
2011). Also, Rao and Hess (2009) argue there is the possibility that some
current insurance schemes may increase maladaptation. Under-insurance
can also arise when agents expect that the public sector will provide
disaster assistance. Some refer to this as the Samaritan’s dilemma
(Gibson et al., 2005; Raschky et al., 2013).
17.5.2. Payments for Environmental Services
Payments for environmental services (PES) pay landholders or farmers
for actions that preserve the services to public and environmental health
provided by ecosystems on their property, including services that
contribute to both climate change adaptation and mitigation. There are
ample cases of mitigation-focused PES schemes (e.g., Pagiola, 2008;
Wunder and Albán, 2008; Wunder and Borner, 2011), and more recently
emerging evidence of the use of PES in adaptation which are of pilot
nature and location-specific, however (Butzengeiger-Geyer et al.,
2011; Schultz, 2012; van de Sand, 2012). Potentially well designed PES
schemes offer a framework for adaptation and there is a view among
development agencies that with more experience and guidance on
implementation PES might well contribute to adaptation as one of a
multitude of feasible measures (e.g., taxes, charges, subsidies, loans).
Chishakwe et al. (2012) draw comparisons and find synergies between
PES community-based natural resources management approaches in
southern Africa and community-based adaptation.
17.5.3. Improved Resource Pricing and Water Markets
Studies of water sector adaptation often begin by citing the implications
of future water shortages and the potential for conflict. Techniques
frequently cited for resolving these conflicts include the establishment
of water markets or water pricing schemes (e.g., Vorosmarty et al., 2000;
Adler, 2008; Alavian et al., 2009), which is in itself, however, also often
associated with conflict (Miller et al., 1997). Traditionally water markets
facilitate transfer from lower to higher-valued uses (Olmstead, 2010)
but pricing rules can also function through urban fees and real estate
taxes (as they do for water supply and urban stormwater regulation in
many countries). A few studies make the case that water markets and
pricing improves climate change adaptation (Medellin-Azuara et al.,
2008). In many cases, the projected increase in climate-induced water
demand (particularly in the agriculture sector), coupled with a projected
decrease in water supply, suggests that adaptation will be needed.
Many countries have instituted structures for water pricing in the
household and agricultural sectors. Nevertheless such prices are unevenly
965
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
applied, collection rates are low, metering is rarely implemented (at
least for the agricultural sector, which is typically the largest water
user), and pricing is often based on annual rather than usage-based
fees (Saleth et al., 2012). In many countries, a number of important
institutional barriers to water markets and pricing remain. These include
a lack of property rights including a thorough consideration of historical
and current entitlements, limits on transferability, legal and physical
infrastructures, and institutional shortcomings (Turral et al., 2005; Saleth
et al., 2012) coupled with issues involved with return flows, third-party
impacts, market design, transactions costs, and average versus marginal
cost pricing (Griffin, 2012).
17.5.4. Charges, Subsidies, and Taxes
The environmental economics literature over the past 30 years has
emphasized the importance of market-based instruments (MBIs) relative
to command and control regulations. MBIs are shown to be generally
more cost effective, providing stronger incentives for innovation and
dynamic efficiency. Within the wide range of instruments that qualify as
market based, there is a general preference in terms of overall efficiency
for taxes over subsidies (Sterner, 2002; Barbier and Markandya, 2012).
MBIs include charges on harmful emissions and wastes, subsidies to
clean energy, subsidized loans, and others.
Frequently Asked Questions
FAQ 17.3 | In what ways can economic instruments facilitate adaptation
to climate change in developed and developing countries?
Economic instruments (EIs) are designed to make more efficient use of scarce resources and to ensure that risks are
m
ore effectively shared between agents in society. EIs can include taxes, subsidies, risk sharing, and risk transfer
(including insurance), water pricing, intellectual property rights, or other tools that send a market signal that shapes
behavior. In the context of adaptation, EIs are useful in a number of ways.
First, they help establish an efficient use of the resources that will be affected by climate change: water pricing is an
example. If water is already priced properly, there will be less overuse that has to be corrected through adaptation
measures should supplies become more scarce.
Second, EIs can function as flexible, low-cost tools to identify adaptation measures. Using the water supply example
again, if climate change results in increasing water scarcity, EIs can easily identify adjustments in water rates needed
to bring demand into balance with the new supply, which can be less costly than finding new ways to increase supply.
Insurance is a common economic instrument that serves as a flexible, low-cost adaptation tool. Where risks are
well defined, insurance markets can set prices and insurance availability to encourage choices and behaviors that
can help reduce vulnerability, and also generate a pool of funds for post-disaster recovery. Insurance discounts for
policy holders who undertake building modifications that reduce flood risk, for example, are one way that EIs can
encourage adaptive behavior.
Payments for environmental services (PES) schemes are another economic instrument that encourages adaptive
behavior. This approach pays landholders or farmers for actions that preserve the services to public and environmental
health provided by ecosystems on their property, including services that contribute to both climate change mitigation
and adaptation. A PES approach is being used in Costa Rica to manage natural resources broadly, for example.
Paying timber owners not to cut down forests that serve as carbon sinks (the idea behind the Reduced Emissions
from Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD) proposal to the United Nations Framework Convention on
Climate Change (UNFCCC)) or paying farmers not to cultivate land in order reduce erosion damage (as is being
done in China and the USA) are examples. In developed countries, where markets function reasonably well, EIs can
be directly deployed through market mechanisms. In developing countries (and also in some developed ones),
however, this is not always the case and markets often need government action and support. For example, private
insurance companies sometimes don’t cover all risks, or they set rates that are not affordable, and public intervention
is required to make sure the insurance is available and affordable. Government also has an important role in
ensuring that voluntary market instruments work effectively and fairly, through legal frameworks that define property
rights involving scarce resources such as land and water in areas where such rights are not well established. An
example of this is the conflict between regions over the use of rivers for water supply and hydropower, when those
rivers flow from one jurisdiction to the next and ownership of the water is not clearly established by region-wide
agreements. PES schemes can only function well when the public sector ensures that rights are defined and
agreements honored.
966
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
I
n many cases climate change exacerbates the effects of pricing
resources below their social costs. This is true for some forms of energy
(e.g., hydro- and fossil fuel-based) as well as many ecosystem services. If
these resources were optimally priced, there would be greater incentives
to investment in clean technologies and the need for additional public
sector adaptation measures would be lessened (ESMAP, 2010).
In addition to the instruments already identified, others that are potentially
important include raising the price of energy through a tax (Sterner,
2011), developing markets for genetic resources (Markandya and Nunes,
2012), and strengthening property rights so schemes such as PES can
be more effective. These measures are desirable even in the absence of
climate change; they become even more so when climate impacts are
accounted for. Yet it is important to note that though the case for such
social cost pricing through the use of charges is strong, it also has its
limitations. Higher prices for key commodities can hurt the poor and
vulnerable and complementary measures may need to be taken to
address such effects.
17.5.5. Intellectual Property Rights
Technology transfer is increasingly seen as an important means of
adaptation because of the global benefits it provides through the
transfer of knowledge. Christiansen et al. (2011), in a Technology Needs
Assessments carried out in developing countries, list about 165
technological needs related to mitigation and adaptation. Examples
include applications to agriculture in Cambodia and Bangladesh and
coastal zones in Thailand. In many of these cases patents and other
intellectual property protection constrain technology transfer. Patent
buy-outs, patent pools, compulsory licenses, and other open source
approaches have been used to relax this constraint (Dutz and Sharma,
2012). Patent buy-outs involve third parties (e.g., international financial
institutions or foundations) acquiring the marketing rights for a
patented product in a developing country. Patent pools represent a
group of patent holders who agree to license their individual patents
to each other (closed pool) or to any party (open pool). Compulsory
licenses are issued by governments and allow patent rights to be
overridden in critical situations. For all the above reasons, therefore, it
is suggested that limits to technology transfer are limiting climate
change adaptation (Henry and Stiglitz, 2010). There is also the view,
however, that strong intellectual property (IP) protection in receiving
countries is facilitating technology transfer from advanced countries,
and the evidence indicates a systematic impact of IP protection on
technology transfer through exports, FDI, and technology licensing,
particularly for middle-income countries for which the risk of imitation
in the absence of such protection is relatively high.
17.5.6. Innovation and Research & Development Subsidies
Subsidies to encourage innovation through research and development
(R&D) may be employed as a measure to encourage adaptation
investments as well as behavioral change (Bräuninger at al., 2011).
Subsidies involve direct payments, tax reductions, or price supports that
enhance the rewards from the implementation of an activity (Gupta et
al., 2007). There has been some criticism of the efficiency of subsidies
i
n terms of rent seeking and adverse effects on competitiveness (Barbier
and Markandya, 2012). They are often poorly targeted and end up
getting captured by middle and upper income groups. Moreover, they
imply increasing budgetary burdens. Yet they are popular with decision
makers and the wider public. Subsidies are today mostly used for
reasons other than climate adaptation, and evidence regarding its use
for adaptation as well as regarding the incentivizing of adaptation R&D
specifically is missing. Popp (2004) is partly an exception, which focuses
on subsidies for mitigation. It shows that such subsidies have little
impact on their own but they do work to enhance the effects of
other instruments such as energy taxes and regulations that mandate
improvements in energy efficiency and the use of lower carbon options.
17.5.7. The Role of Behavior
It is well recognized that often human behavior is characterized by
bounded rationality, particularly in relation to choices under risk
and uncertainty, which affects the effectiveness of incentive-based
approaches. Individuals may over- or underestimate risks (Ellsberg,
1961; Kahneman and Tversky, 1979), and may not consistently weigh
long-term consequences (Ainslie, 1975). One well documented
explanation is that individuals do not fully use available information on
risks when they make their choices (Magat et al., 1987; Camerer and
Kunreuther, 1989; Hogarth and Kunreuther, 1995). Policies that well
consider such risk perceptions and behavioral biases increase their
efficiency. For instance, people react differently to abstract information
on distant events as opposed to concrete, current, emotionally charged
information (Trope and Liberman, 2003). In practice, this can limit the
impact of simply communicating “dry,emotion-free information, such
as that on flood return periods, and underlines the importance of
participatory, reflexive, and iterative approaches to decision support
(Fischhoff et al., 1978; Slovic, 1997; Renn, 2008; IRGC, 2010; see also
Section 2.1.2).
References
Aaheim, H.A. and C. Bretteville, 2001: Decision-Making Frameworks for Climate
Policy under Uncertainty. Working Paper 2001-02, Center for International
Climate and Environmental Research (CICERO), Oslo, Norway, 30 pp.
Aakre, S. and D.T. Rübbelke, 2010: Adaptation to climate change in the European
Union: efficiency versus equity considerations. Environmental Policy and
Governance, 20(3), 159-179.
Aakre, S., I. Banaszak, R. Mechler, D. Rübbelke, A. Wreford, and H. Kalirai, 2009:
Financial adaptation to disaster risk in the European Union: improving roles
for the public sector. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change,
15(7), 721-736, doi:10.1007/s11027-010-9232-3.
Adger, W.N., 2003: Social capital, collective action, and adaptation to climate change.
Economic Geography, 79 (4), 387-404.
Adger, W.N., N.W. Arnell, and E.L. Tompkins, 2005a: Successful adaptation to climate
change across scales. Global Environmental Change, 15(2), 77-86.
Adger W.N., K. Brown, and E.L. Tompkins, 2005b: The political economy of cross-
scale networks in resource co-management. Ecology and Society, 10(2), 9,
www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol10/iss2/art9/.
Adger, W.N., J. Paavola, S. Huq, and M.J. Mace (eds.), 2006: Fairness in Adaptation
to Climate Change. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, USA, 319 pp.
Adger, W.N., S. Agrawala, M.M.Q. Mirza, C. Conde, K. O’Brien, J. Pulhin, R. Pulwarty,
B. Smit, and K. Takahashi, 2007: Assessment of adaptation practices, options,
constraints and capacity. Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and
Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment
967
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Parry, M.L., O.F.
Canziani, J.P. Palutikof, P.J. van der Linden, and C.E. Hanson (eds.)] Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 717-743.
Adger, W.N., S. Dessai, M. Goulden, M. Hulme, I. Lorenzon, D.R. Nelson, L.O. Naess,
J. Wolf, and A. Wreford, 2009: Are there social limits to adaptation to climate
change? Climatic Change, 93, 335-354.
Adler, J.H., 2008: Water marketing as an adaptive response to the threat of climate
change. Hamline Law Review, 31(3), 729-754.
Agrawala, S. and S. Fankhauser (eds.), 2008: Economic Aspects of Adaptation to
Climate Change: Costs, Benefits and Policy Instruments. OECD Publishing, Paris,
France, 134 pp.
Agrawala, S., F. Bosello, C. Carraro, E. de Cian, and E. Lanzi, 2011: Adapting to climate
change: costs, benefits, and modelling approaches. International Review of
Environmental and Resource Economics, 5(3), 245-284.
Ainslie, G., 1975: Specious reward: a behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse
control. Psychological Bulletin, 82(4), 463-496.
Alavian, V., H.M. Qaddumi, E. Dickson, S.M. Diez, A.V. Danilenko, R.F. Hirji, G. Puz, C.
Pizarro, M. Jacobsen, and B. Blankespoor, 2009: Water and Climate Change:
Understanding the Risks and Making Climate-Smart Investment Decisions. The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 140 pp.
Alston, J.M. and B.H. Hurd, 1990: Some neglected social costs of government spending
in farm programs.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72 (1), 149-156.
Arrow, K.J. and A.C. Fisher, 1974: Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and
irreversibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88, 312-319.
Arrow, K.J., M.L. Cropper, G.C. Eads, R.W. Hahn, L.B. Lave, R.G. Noll, P.R. Portney, M.
Russel, R.L. Schmalensee, V.K. Smith, and R.N. Stavins, 1996: Benefit-Cost Analysis
in Environmental, Health, and Safety Regulation. American Enterprise Institute
for Public Policy Research (AEI), The Annapolis Center, and Resources for the
Future, AEI Press, c/o Publisher, Resources, Inc., La Verge, TN, USA, 18 pp.
Arrow, K., M. Cropper, C. Gollier, B. Groom, G. Heal, R. Newell, W. Nordhaus, R.
Pindyck, W. Pizer, P. Portney, T. Sterner, R.S.J. Toll, and M. Weitzman, 2013: Policy
Forum: Determining benefits and costs for future generations. Science,
341(6144), 349-350.
Asquith, N., M.T. Vargas, and S. Wunder, 2008: Selling two environmental services:
in-kind payments for bird habitat and watershed protection in Los Negros,
Bolivia. Ecological Economics, 65, 675-684.
Atkinson, A.B. and J.E. Stiglitz, 1980: Lectures in Public Economics. McGraw-Hill Book
Company, Singapore, 619 pp.
Attavanich, W., B.A. McCarl, Z. Ahmedov, S.W. Fuller, and D.V. Vedenov, 2013: Climate
change and infrastructure: effects of climate change on U.S. grain transport.
Nature Climate Change, 3, 638-643.
Barbier, E.B. and A. Markandya, 2012: A New Blueprint for a Green Economy.
Routledge, Abingdon, UK and New York, NY, USA, 216 pp.
Barr, R., S. Fankhauser, and K. Hamilton, 2010: Adaptation investments: a resource
allocation framework. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change,
15(8), 843-858, doi:10.1007/s11027-010-9242-1.
Barsky, R.B., F.T. Juster, M.S. Kimball, and M.D. Shapiro, 1997: Preference parameters
and behavioral heterogeneity: an experimental approach in the health and
retirement study. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 537-579.
Bateman, I.J., R. Brouwer, S. Ferrini, M. Schaafsma, D.N. Barton, A. Dubgaard, B. Hasler,
S. Hime, I. Liekens, S. Navrud, L. De Nocker, R. Ščeponavičiūtė, and D. Semėnienė,
2011: Making benefit transfers work: deriving and testing principles for value
transfers for similar and dissimilar sites using a case study of the non-market
benefits of water quality improvements across Europe. Environmental and
Resource Economics, 50, 365-387.
Batterbury, S., 2008: Anthropology and global warming: the need for environmental
engagement. Australian Journal of Anthropology, 1, 62-67.
Baum, S.D., 2009: Description, prescription and the choice of discount rates. Ecological
Economics, 69 (1), 197-205.
Baumol, W.G. and W.E. Oates, 1975:The Theory of Environmental Policy: Externalities
Public Outlays, and the Quality of Life. Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ,
USA, 272 pp.
Baylis, K., S. Peplow, G. Rausser, and L. Simon, 2008: Agri-environmental policies in
the EU and United States: a comparison. Ecological Economics, 65, 753-764.
Becken, S., 2005: Harmonising climate change adaptation and mitigation: the case
of tourist resorts in Fiji. Global Environmental Change, 15(4), 381-393.
Beckman, M., 2011: Converging and conflicting interests in adaptation to environmental
change in Central Vietnam. Climate and Development, 3(1), 32-41.
Bell, M., R. Goldberg, C. Hogrefe, P.L. Kinney, K. Knowlton, B. Lynn, J. Rosenthal, C.
Rosenzweig, and J. Patz, 2007: Climate change, ambient ozone, and health in
50 US cities. Climatic Change, 82, 61-76.
Belton, V. and T.J Stewart, 2002: Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: An Integrated
Approach. Springer Science, Dordrecht, Netherlands, 372 pp.
Beltratti, A., G. Chichilnisky, and G. Heal, 1998: Uncertain future preferences and
conservation. In: Sustainability: Dynamics and Uncertainty [Chichilnisky, G.,
G.M. Heal, and A. Vercelli (eds.)]. Vol. 9 of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM)
series on economics, energy, and environment, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
Dordrecht, Netherlands, pp. 257-275.
Ben-Haim, Y., 2001: Information-Gap Decision Theory: Decisions under Severe
Uncertainty. Academic Press, San Diego, CA, USA, 330 pp.
Berkhout, F., J. Hertin, and D.M. Gann, 2006: Learning to adapt: organisational
adaptation to climate change impacts. Climatic Change, 78(1), 135-156.
Bernstein, P., 1996: Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk. John Wiley &
Sons, Hoboken, NJ, USA, 383 pp.
Biesbroek, R., J. Klostermann, C. Termeer, and P. Kabat, 2011: Barriers to climate
change adaptation in the Netherlands. Climate Law, 2(2), 181-199.
Birthal, P.S., S.N. Nigam, A.V. Narayanan, and K.A. Kareem, 2011: An Economic
Assessment of the Potential Benefits of Breeding for Drought Tolerance in
Crops: A Case of Groundnut in India. Research Bulletin No. 25, International
Crops Research Institute for the Semi-Arid Tropics (ICRISAT), Andhra Pradesh,
India, 36 pp., ec2-50-19-248-237.compute-1.amazonaws.com/285/1/115-2011_
RB25_an_econ_assess.pdf.
Bizikova, L., S. Burch, S. Cohen, and J. Robinson, 2010: Linking sustainable development
with climate change adaptation and mitigation. In: Climate Change, Ethics and
Human Security [O’Brien, K., A. St. Clair, and B. Kristoffersen (eds.)]. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 157-179.
Bjarnadottir, S., Y. Li, and M.G. Stewart, 2011: A probabilistic-based framework for
impact and adaptation assessment of climate change on hurricane damage
risks and costs. Structural Safety, 33(3), 173-185.
Blaikie, P., B. Wisner, T. Cannon, and I. Davis, 1994: At Risk: Natural Hazards, People’s
Vulnerability and Disaster. 1
st
edn., Routledge, Abingdon, UK and New York, NY,
USA, 284 pp.
Blankespoor, B., S. Dasgupta, B. Laplante, and D. Wheeler, 2010: The Economics of
Adaptation to Extreme Weather Events in Developing Countries. World Bank
Discussion Paper No.1 in the Development and Climate Change Series, The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 22 pp.
Bosello, F., R. Roson, and R.S.J. Tol, 2007: Economy wide estimates of the implications
of climate change: sea level rise. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37,
549-571.
Botzen, W.J.W., J.C.J.H. Aerts, and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, 2009: Willingness of
homeowners to mitigate climate risk through insurance. Ecological Economics,
68, 2265-2277.
Bouwer, L.M., 2010: Disasters and Climate Change: Analysis and Methods for
Projecting Future Losses from Extreme Weather. Ph.D. Thesis, The Institute for
Environmental Studies (IVM), Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam, Netherlands, 127
pp., ISBN 978-90-8570-596-3.
Brander, L.M., I. Bräuer, H. Gerdes, A. Ghermandi, O. Kuik, A. Markandya, S. Navrud,
P.A.L.D. Nunes, M. Schaafsma H. Vos, and A. Wagtendonk, 2012: Using meta-
analysis and GIS for value transfer and scaling up: valuing climate change
induced losses of European wetlands. Environmental Resource Economics, 52,
395-413.
Brauch, H.G., 2009a: Introduction: facing global environmental change and
sectorialization of security. In: Facing Global Environmental Change:
Environmental, Human, Energy, Food, Health and Water Security Concepts
[Brauch, H.G., N.C. Behera, P. Kameri-Mbote, J. Grin, Ú. Oswald Spring, B.
Chourou, C. Mesjasz, and H. Krummenacher (eds.)]. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg,
Germany, pp. 27-44.
Brauch, H.G., 2009b: Securitizing global environmental change. In: Facing Global
Environmental Change: Environmental, Human, Energy, Food, Health and Water
Security Concepts [Brauch, H.G., N.C. Behera, P. Kameri-Mbote, J. Grin, Ú.
Oswald Spring, B. Chourou, C. Mesjasz, and H. Krummenacher (eds.)]. Springer,
Berlin Heidelberg, Germany, pp. 65-102.
Bräuninger, M., S. Butzengeiger-Geyer, A. Dlugolecki, S. Hochrainer, K. Köhler, J.
Linnerooth-Bayer, R. Mechler, A. Michaelowa, and S. Schulze, 2011: Application
of Economic Instruments for Adaptation to Climate Change. CLIMA.C.3./ETU/
2010/0011, Perspectives GmbH Hamburg, Germany Office, Final Report to the
968
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
European Commission, Directorate General, CLIMA, Brussels, Belgium, 326 pp.,
ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/adaptation/what/docs/economic_instruments_en.pdf.
Brent, R.J., 1996: Applied Cost-Benefit Analysis. Edward Elgar Publishing, Ltd.,
Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA, 336 pp.
Brooks, M., F. Gagnon-Lebrun, H. Harvey, C. Sauvé, and ÉcoRessources Consultants,
2009: Prioritizing Climate Change Risks and Actions on Adaptation: A Review
of Selected Institutions, Tools, and Approaches. Final Report Prepared for the
Government of Canada, Policy Research Initiative (PRI), PRI Project, Sustainable
Development, PRI, Ottawa, ON, Canada, 56 pp.
Brooks, N., W.N. Adger, and M.P. Kelly, 2005: The determinants of vulnerability and
adaptive capacity at the national level and the implications for adaptation.
Global Environmental Change, 15(2), 151-163.
Brouwer, R. and R. van Ek, 2004: Integrated ecological, economic and social impact
assessment of alternative flood control policies in the Netherlands. Ecological
Economics, 50 (1-2), 1-21, doi:16/j.ecolecon.2004.01.020.
Brown, C., W. Werick, W. Leger, and D. Fay, 2011: A decision analytic approach to
managing climate risks – application to the Upper Great Lakes. Journal of the
American Water Resources Association, 47, 524-534.
Brown, D.J. and G. Heal, 1979: Equity, efficiency and increasing returns. The Review
of Economic Studies, 46, 571-585.
Bulir, A. and A.J. Hamann, 2008: Volatility of development aid: from the frying pan
into the fire? World Development, 36(10), 2048-2066.
Burby, R.J., A.C. Nelson, D. Parker, and J. Handmer, 2001: Urban containment policy
and exposure to natural hazards: is there a connection? Journal of Environmental
Planning and Management, 44(4), 475-490.
Burby, J.R., 2006: Hurricane Katrina and the paradoxes of government disaster policy:
bringing about wise governmental decisions for hazardous areas. The ANNALS
of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 604(1), 171-191.
Burby, R.J., A.B. Cigler, S.P. French, E.J. Kaiser, J. Kartez, D. Roenigk, D. Weist, and D.
Whittington, 1991: Sharing Environmental Risks: How to Control Governments’
Losses in Natural Disasters. Westview Press, Boulder, CO, USA, 280 pp.
Burton, I., 2004: Climate change and the adaptation deficit. In: Climate Change:
Building the Adaptive Capacity [Fenech, A., D. MacIver, H. Auld, R. Bing Rong,
and Y. Yin (ed.)]. Environment Canada, Meteorological Service of Canada,
Gatineau, QC, Canada, pp. 25-33.
Burtraw, D., A. Krupnick, K. Palmer, A. Paul, M. Toma, and C. Bloyd, 2003: Ancillary
benefits of reduced air pollution in the US from moderate greenhouse gas
mitigation policies in the electricity sector. Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, 45, 650-673
Butt, T.A., B.A. McCarl, and A.O. Kergna, 2006: Policies for reducing agricultural sector
vulnerability to climate change in Mali. Climate Policy, 5, 583-598.
Callaway, J.M., 2004: Adaptation benefits and costs: are they important in the global
policy picture and how can we estimate them? Global Environmental Change,
14(3), 273-282.
Callaway, J. and M. Hellmuth, 2007: Assessing the Incremental Benefits and Costs
of Coping with Development Pressure and Climate Change: A South African
Case Study. Submissions from admitted non-governmental organizations on
socio-economic information under the Nairobi work programme, United Nations
Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), Geneva, Switzerland,
1 pp.
Camerer, C.F. and H. Kunreuther, 1989: Decision processes for low probability events:
policy implications. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 8, 565-592.
Carraro, C. and A. Sgobbi, 2008: Climate Change Impacts and Adaptation Strategies
in Italy: An Economic Assessment. NOTA DI LAVORO 6.2008, Fondazione Eni
Enrico Mattei, Milan, Italy, 26 pp., www.feem.it/userfiles/attach/Publication/
NDL2008/NDL2008-006.pdf.
Carter, T.R., M.L. Parry, H. Harasawa, and S. Nishioka, 1994: IPCC Technical Guidelines
for Assessing Climate Change Impacts and Adaptations. Part of the IPCC Special
Report to the First Session of the Conference of the Parties to the UN Framework
Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), World Meteorological Organization
(WMO) and the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), Published by
the Department of Geography, University College London, London, UK and the
Center for Global Environmental Research, National Institute for Environmental
Studies, Tsukuba, Japan, with the assistance of the UK Department of the
Environment and the Environment Agency of Japan, 59 pp., www.ipcc-wg3.de/
special-reports/.files-images/ipcc-technical-guidelines-1994n.pdf.
Carter, T.R., R.N. Jones, X. Lu, S. Bhadwal, C. Conde, L.O. Mearns, B.C. O’Neill,
M.D.A. Rounsevell, and M.B. Zurek, 2007: New assessment methods and the
characterisation of future conditions. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts,
Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth
Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Parry,
M.L., O.F. Canziani, J.P. Palutikof, P.J. van der Linden, and C.E. Hanson (eds.)].
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, pp. 133-171.
Chichilnisky, G., A. Beltratti, and G. Heal, 1998: Chapter 2.1: Sustainable use of
renewable resources. In: Sustainability: Dynamics and Uncertainty [Chichilnisky,
G., G. Heal, and A. Vercelli (eds.)]. Vol. 9 of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM)
series on economics, energy, and environment, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
Dordrecht, Netherlands, pp. 49-76.
Chinowsky, P. and J. Price, 2013: Assessment of climate change adaptation costs for
the U.S. road network. Global Environmental Change, 23(4), 764-773.
Chishakwe, N., L. Murray, and M. Chambwera, 2012: Building Climate Change
Adaptation on Community Experiences: Lessons from Community-Based
Natural Resource Management in Southern Africa. International Institute for
Environment and Development (IIED), London, UK, 126 pp.
Chopra, K., 2005: Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: Policy Responses, Volume 3.
Island Press, Washington, DC, USA, 621 pp.
Christiansen, L., A. Olhoff, and S. Traerup, 2011: Technologies for Adaptation:
Perspectives and Practical Experiences. UNEP Risø Centre on Energy, Climate
and Sustainable Development, Roskilde, Denmark, 123 pp.
Cimato, F. and M. Mullan, 2010: Adapting to Climate Change: Analysing the Role of
Government. DEFRA Evidence and Analysis Series Paper 1, Department for
Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA), London, UK, 79 pp.
Claassen, R., A. Cattaneo, and R. Johansson, 2008: Cost-effective design of agri-
environmental payment programs: U.S. experience in theory and practice.
Ecological Economics, 65, 737-752.
CMEPSP, 2009: Report of the Commission on the Measurement of Economic
Performance and Social Progress. The Commission on the Measurement of
Economic Performance and Social Progress (CMEPSP), Paris, France, 291 pp.
Coase, R.H., 1937: The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386-405.
Coase, R.H., 1960: The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1-44.
Cohen, M. and J. Sebstad, 2003: Reducing Vulnerability: The Demand for Micro-
insurance. An Initiative of Austria/CGAP/DFID/UNDP, MicroSave-Africa, Nairobi,
Kenya, 61 pp.
Cohen, M. and J. Sebstad, 2005: Reducing vulnerability: the demand for micro-
insurance. Journal of International Development, 17(3), 397-474.
Comim, F., 2008: Climate injustice and development: a capability perspective.
Development, 51, 344-349.
Collier, B., J. Skees, and B. Barnett, 2009: Weather index insurance and climate
change: opportunities and challenges in lower income countries. The Geneva
Papers, 34(3), 401-424, doi:10.1057/gpp.2009.11.
Dalby, S., 2009: Security and Environmental Change. Polity Press, Cambridge, UK and
Malden, MA, USA, 197 pp.
DCLG, 2009: Multi-Criteria Analysis: A Manual. UK Department for Communities and
Local Government (DCLG), Communities and Local Government Publications,
Wetherby, West Yorkshire, UK, 165 pp.
de Bruin, K., 2011: An Economic Analysis of Adaptation to Climate Change Under
Uncertainty. Ph.D. Thesis, Wageningen University, Wageningen, Netherlands,
179 pp.
de Bruin, K., R.B. Dellink, A. Ruijs, L. Bolwidt, A. Van Buuren, J. Graveland, R.S. De
Groot, P.J. Kuikman, S. Reinhard, R.P. Roetter, V.C. Tassone, A. Verhagen, and
E.C. van Ierland, 2009a: Adapting to climate change in The Netherlands: an
inventory of climate adaptation options and ranking of alternatives. Climatic
Change, 95 (1), 23-45.
de Bruin, K.C., R.B. Dellink, and R.S.J. Tol, 2009b: AD-DICE: an implementation of
adaptation in the DICE model. Climatic Change, 95 (1-2), 63-81.
de Bekker-Grob, E.W., M. Ryan, and K. Gerard, 2012: Discrete choice experiments
in health economics: a review of the literature. Health Economics, 21(2), 145-
172.
DeCanio, S.J., 2007: Reflections on Climate Change, Economic Development, and
Global Equity. Presented at the 2007 Leontief Prize Ceremony, Tufts University,
Global Development and Environment Institute, October 17, 2007, 19 pp.,
www.ase.tufts.edu/gdae/about_us/leontief/DeCanioLeontief07.pdf.
De Lucena, A.F.P., R. Schaeffer, and A.S. Szklo, 2010: Least-cost adaptation options
for global climate change impacts on the Brazilian electric power system.
Global Environmental Change, 20(2) 342-350.
Dellink, R., M. den Elzen, H. Aiking, E. Bergsma, F. Berkhout, T. Dekker, and J. Gupta,
2009: Sharing the burden of financing adaptation to climate change. Global
Environmental Change, 19(4), 411-421.
969
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
Delmer, D.P., C. Nottenburg, G.D. Graff, and A.B. Bennett, 2003: Intellectual property
resources for international development in agriculture. Plant Physiology,
133(4), 1666-1670.
Deschenes, O. and M. Greenstone, 2007: The economic impacts of climate change:
evidence from agricultural output and random fluctuations in weather.
American Economic Review, 97, 354-385.
Dessai, S., 2003: Heat stress and mortality in Lisbon part II. An assessment of the
potential impacts of climate change. International Journal of Biometeorology,
48(1), 37-44.
Dessai , S. and M. Hulme, 2007: Assessing the robustness of adaptation decisions to
climate change uncertainties: a case study on water resources management
in the East of England. Global Environmental Change, 17, 59-72.
Dessai, S., M. Hulme, R. Lempert, and R. Pielke, Jr., 2009a: Climate prediction: a limit
to adaptation? In: Adapting to Climate Change: Thresholds, Values, Governance
[Adger, W.N., I. Lorenzoni, and K.L. O’Brien (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 64-78.
Dessai, S., M. Hulme, R. Lempert, and R. Pielke, Jr., 2009b: Do we need better predictions
to adapt to a changing climate? Eos, 90(13), 111-112.
Dietz, S., C. Hope, and N. Patmore, 2009: Some economics of “dangerous” climate
change: reflections on the Stern Review. Global Environmental Change,
17(3-4), 311-325.
Dobbs, T.L. and J. Pretty, 2008: Case study of agri-environmental payments: the
United Kingdom. Ecological Economics, 65, 765-775.
Dobes, L. and J. Bennett, 2009: Multi-criteria analysis: “good enough” for government
work? Agenda, 16(3), 7-30.
Dutz, M.A. and S. Sharma, 2102: Green Growth, Technology and Innovation. Policy
Research Working Paper 5932, the Economic Policy and Debt Department,
Poverty Reduction and Economic Management, The International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA,
45 pp.
Easterling, W.E., P.R. Crosson, N.J. Rosenberg, M.S. McKenney, L.A. Katz, and K.M.
Lemon, 1993: Paper 2. Agricultural impacts of and responses to climate change
in the Missouri-Iowa-Nebraska-Kansas (MINK) region. Climatic Change,
24(1-2), 23-61.
Ebi, K.L., 2008: Adaptation costs for climate change-related cases of diarrhoeal dis-
ease, malnutrition, and malaria in 2030. Global Health, 4, 9, doi:10.1186/1744-
8603-4-9.
Ebi, K.L. and I. Burton, 2008: Identifying practical adaptation options: an approach
to address climate change-related health risks. Environmental Science & Policy,
11(4), 359-369.
ECA, 2009: Shaping Climate-Resilient Development: A Framework for Decision-
Making. A Report of the Economics of Climate Adaptation Working Group,
Economics of Climate Adaptation (ECA), a partnership of the ClimateWorks
Foundation, Global Environment Facility (GEF), European Commission (EC),
McKinsey & Company, The Rockefeller Foundation, Standard Chartered Bank,
and Swiss Re, 159 pp.
Egbendewe-Mondzozo, A., M. Musumba, B.A. McCarl, and X.M. Wu, 2011: Climate
change and vector-borne diseases: an economic impact analysis of malaria in
Africa. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 8(3),
913-930.
Eisenack, K., 2013: The inefficiency of private adaptation to pollution in the presence
of endogenous market structure. Environmental and Resource Economics (in
press), doi:10.1007/s10640-013-9667-6.
Elbehri, A., A. Genest, and M. Burfisher, 2011: Global Action on Climate Change in
Agriculture: Linkages to Food Security, Markets and Trade Policies in Developing
Countries. Trade and Markets Division, Food and Agriculture Organization of
the United Nations (FAO), Rome, Italy, 82 pp.
Elsasser, H. and R. Bürki, 2002: Climate change as a threat to tourism in the Alps.
Climate Research, 20, 253-257.
Engel, S. and C. Palmer, 2008: Payments for environmental services as an alternative
to logging under weak property rights: the case of Indonesia. Ecological
Economics, 65, 799-809.
Engel, S., S. Pagiola, and S. Wunder, 2008: Designing payments for environmental
services in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecological Economics,
65, 663-674.
Eriksen, S., P. Aldunce, C.S. Bahinipati, R. Martins, J.I. Molefe, C. Nhemachena, K.
O’Brien, F. Olorunfemi, J. Park, L. Sygna, and K. Ulsrud, 2011: When not every
response to climate change is a good one: identifying principles for sustainable
adaptation. Climate and Development, 3(1), 7-20.
ESMAP, 2010: Climate Impacts on Energy Systems: Key Issues for Energy Sector
Adaptation. Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (ESMAP) Studies and
The World Bank, The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
/ The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 178 pp.
European Environmental Agency, 2007: Climate Change: The Cost of Inaction
and the Cost of Adaptation. EEA Technical Report No. 13/2007, European
Environmental Agency (EEA), Office for Official Publications of the European
Communities, Luxembourg, Luxembourg, 67 pp.
Fankhauser, S., 1995: Protection versus retreat: the economic costs of sea-level rise.
Environment and Planning A, 27(2), 299-319.
Fankhauser, S., 2010: The costs of adaptation. Wiley Interdisciplinary Review Climate
Change, 1(1), 23-30.
Fankhauser, S. and R. Soare, 2013: An economic approach to adaptation: illustrations
from Europe. Climatic Change, 118, 367-379.
Fankhauser, S. and R.S.J. Tol, 2005: On climate change and economic growth.
Resource and Energy Economics, 27(1), 1-17.
Fankhauser, S., J.B. Smith, and R.S.J. Tol, 1999: Weathering climate change: some
simple rules to guide adaptation decisions. Ecological Economics, 30(1), 67-78.
Farber, D., 2007: Basic compensation for victims of climate change. University of
Pennsylvania Law Review, 155(6), 1605-1656.
Finger, R., W. Hediger, and S. Schmid, 2011: Irrigation as adaptation strategy to
climate change a biophysical and economic appraisal for Swiss maize
production. Climatic Change, 105(3-4), 509-528.
Fischhoff, B., P. Slovic, S. Lichtenstein, S. Read, and B. Combs, 1978: How safe is safe
enough? A psychometric study of attitudes towards technological risks and
benefits. Policy Sciences, 9(2), 127-152.
Ford, J.D., T. Pearce, J. Prno, F. Duerden, L.B. Ford, T.R. Smith, and M. Beaumier, 2011:
Canary in a coal mine: perceptions of climate change risks and response options
among Canadian mine operations. Climatic Change, 109(3-4), 399-415.
Freeman, M., 2003: The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. 2
nd
edn., Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, USA, 491
pp.
Friedman, M., 1953:Essays in Positive Economics. University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, IL, USA, 328 pp.
Frihy, O.E., 2001: The necessity of environmental impact assessment (EIA) in
implementing coastal projects: lessons learned from the Egyptian
Mediterranean Coast. Ocean & Coastal Management, 44(7-8), 489-516.
Frost, P.G.H. and I. Bond, 2008: The CAMPFIRE programme in Zimbabwe: payments
for wildlife services. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 776-787.
Froyn, C.B., 2005: Decision criteria, scientific uncertainty, and the global warming
controversy. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, 10(2),
183-211.
Füssel, H.-M., 2007: Adaptation planning for climate change: concepts, assessment
approaches, and key lessons. Sustainability Science, 2(2), 265-275.
Füssel, H.-M., 2009: Review and Quantitative Analysis of Indices of Climate Change
Exposure, Adaptive Capacity, Sensitivity, and Impacts. Background note to the
World Development Report 2010, The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 34 pp.
Füssel, H.-M., 2010: How inequitable is the global distribution of responsibility,
capability, and vulnerability to climate change: a comprehensive indicator-
based assessment. Global Environmental Change, 20(4), 597-611, doi:10.1016/
j.gloenvcha.2010.07.009.
Füssel, H.-M., 2011: Ethics and international adaptation funding (review essay).
Carbon & Climate Law Review, 5(2), 295-299.
Füssel, H.-M., S. Hallegatte, and M. Reder, 2012: International adaptation funding.
In: Climate Change, Justice and Sustainability: Linking Climate and Development
Policy [Edenhofer, O., J. Wallacher, H. Lotze-Campen, M. Reder, B. Knopf, and J.
Müller (eds.)]. Springer, Dordrecht, Netherlands, pp. 311-330.
Gawel, E., C. Heuson, and P. Lehmann, 2012: Efficient Public Adaptation to Climate
Change: An Investigation of Drivers and Barriers from a Public Choice
Perspective. UFZ Discussion Paper No. 14/2012, Helmholtz-Zentrum für
Umweltforschung GmbH – UFZ, Leipzig, Germany, 27 pp.
Gibson, C.C., K. Andersson, E. Ostrom, and S. Shivakumar, 2005: The Samaritan’s
Dilemma: The Political Economy of Development Aid. Oxford University Press,
New York, NY, USA, 264 pp.
Gilboa, I., 2010: Making Better Decisions: Decision Theory in Practice. Wiley-
Blackwell, Chichester, UK, 232 pp.
Giordano, T., 2012: Adaptive planning for climate change resilient long-lived
infrastructures. Utilities Policy, 23, 80-89.
970
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Goodess, C.M., J.W. Hall, M. Best, R. Betts, L. Cabantous, P.D. Jones, C.G. Kilsby, A.
Pearman, and C.J. Wallace, 2007: Climate scenarios and decision making under
uncertainty. Built Environment, 33(1), 10-30.
Goulden, M., D. Conway, and A. Persechino, 2009: Adaptation to climate change in
international river basins in Africa: a review/Adaptation au changement
climatique dans les bassins fluviaux internationaux en Afrique: une revue.
Hydrological Sciences Journal, 54(5), 805-828.
Grafakos, S., 2012: Participatory integrated assessment of flood protection measures
for climate adaptation in Dhaka. Environment and Urbanization, 24(1), 197-
213, doi:10.1177/0956247811433538.
Graff, G.D., S.E. Cullen, K.J. Bradford, D. Zilberman, and A.B. Bennett, 2003: The
public-private structure of intellectual property ownership in agricultural
biotechnology. Nature Biotechnology, 21(9), 989-995.
Grasso, M., 2010: Justice in Funding Adaptation under the International Climate
Change Regime. Springer Science, Dordrecht, Netherlands, 184 pp.
Griffin, R.C., 2012: The origins and ideals of water resource economics in the U.S.
Annual Reviews of Resource Economics, 4, 353-377, doi:10.1146/annurev-
resource-110811-114517.
Grothmann, T. and A. Patt, 2005: Adaptive capacity and human cognition: the process
of individual adaptation to climate change. Global Environmental Change, 15,
199-213.
Groves, D.G. and R.J. Lempert, 2007: A new analytic method for finding policy-
relevant scenarios. Global Environmental Change, 17, 73-85.
Groves, D.G., D. Knopman, R. Lempert, S. Berry, and L. Wainfan, 2007: Presenting
Uncertainty About Climate Change to Water Resource Managers – Summary
of Workshops with the Inland Empire Utilities Agency. Rand Corporation
Technical Report describing research sponsored by the National Science
Foundation and conducted under the auspices of the Environment, Energy, and
Economic Development Program (EEED) within RAND Infrastructure, Safety,
and Environment (ISE), RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, CA, USA, 80 pp.
Groves, D.G., M. Davis, R. Wilkinson, and R. Lempert, 2008: Planning for climate
change in the Inland Empire: Southern California. Water Resources IMPACT,
10(4), 14-17.
Guesnerie, R., 2004: Calcul économique and développment durable. Revue
économique, 55, 363-382.
Gupta, S., D. Tirpak, N. Burger, J. Gupta, N. Höhne, A. Boncheva, G. Kanoan, C. Kolstad,
J. Kruger, A. Michaelowa, S. Murase, J. Pershing, T. Saijo, and A. Sari, 2007: Policies,
instruments and co-operative arrangements. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation
of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment
Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Metz, B., O.R.
Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, and L.A. Meyer (eds)]. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY USA, pp. 746-807.
Hall, J.W., 2007: Probabilistic climate scenarios may misrepresent uncertainty and
lead to bad adaptation decisions. Hydrological Processes, 21(8), 1127-1129.
Hallegatte, S., 2006: A Cost-Benefit Analysis of the New Orleans Flood Protection
System. Regulatory Analysis 06-02, The AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory
Studies, Washington, DC, USA, 18 pp.
Hallegatte, S., 2008: An adaptive regional input-output model and its application
to the assessment of the economic cost of Katrina. Risk Analysis, 28(3), 779-
799.
Hallegatte, S., 2009: Strategies to adapt to an uncertain climate change. Global
Environmental Change, 19, 240-247.
Hallegatte, S., 2012: An Exploration of the Link between Development, Economic
Growth, and Natural Risk. Policy Research Working Paper No. 6216, Office of
the Chief Economist, Sustainable Development Network, Prepared as a
background paper to the World Development Report 2014, The International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC,
USA, 32 pp.
Hallegatte, S. and P. Dumas, 2009: Can natural disasters have positive consequences?
Investigating the role of embodied technical change. Ecological Economics, 68,
777-786.
Hallegatte, S., J.C. Hourcade, and P. Dumas, 2007: Why economic dynamics matter
in assessing climate change damages: illustration on extreme events. Ecological
Economics, 62, 330-340.
Hallegatte, S., F. Lecocq, and C. De Perthuis, 2011a: Designing Climate Change
Adaptation Policies An Economic Framework. Policy Research Working Paper
No. 5568, Office of the Chief Economist, Sustainable Development Network,
The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 39 pp.
Hallegatte, S., V. Przyluski, and A. Vogt-Schilb, 2011b: Building world narratives for
climate change impact, adaptation and vulnerability analyses. Nature Climate
Change, 1, 151-155.
Hallegatte, S., A. Shah, C. Brown, R. Lempert, and S. Gill, 2012: Investment Decision
Making under Deep Uncertainty Application to Climate Change. Policy
Research Working Paper No. 6193, Office of the Chief Economist, Sustainable
Development Network, The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 39 pp.
Handmer, J., Y. Honda, Z. Kundzewicz, N. Arnell, G. Benito, J. Hatfield, I. Mohamed, P.
Peduzzi, S. Wu, B. Sherstyukov, K. Takahashi, and Z. Yan, 2012: Changes in
impacts of climate extremes: human systems and ecosystems. In: Managing
the Risks of Extreme Events and Disasters to Advance Climate Change
Adaptation. A Special Report of Working Groups I and II of the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change [Field, C.B., V. Barros, T.F. Stocker, D. Qin, D.J. Dokken,
K.L. Ebi, M.D. Mastrandrea, K.J. Mach, G.-K. Plattner, S.K. Allen, M. Tignor, and
P.M. Midgley (ed.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York,
NY, USA, pp. 231-290.
Hansen, L.P. and T.J. Sargent, 2008: Robustness. Princeton University Press, Princeton,
NJ, USA, 435 pp.
Hanson, S., R. Nicholls, N. Ranger, S. Hallegatte, J. Corfee-Morlot, C. Herweijer, and J.
Chateau, 2011: A global ranking of port cities with high exposure to climate
extremes. Climatic Change, 104, 89-111.
Harberger, A.C., 1978: On the use of distributional weights in social cost-benefit
analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 86 (2 Pt. 2), S87-S120.
Harberger, A.C., 1984: Basic needs versus distributional weights in social cost-
benefit analysis. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 32(3), 455-474.
Harris, P.G., 2010: World Ethics and Climate Change: From International to Global
Justice. Edinburgh Studies in World Ethics, Edinburgh University Press,
Edinburgh, UK, 214 pp.
Hassan, E., O. Yaqub, and S. Diepeveen, 2010: Intellectual Properties and Developing
Countries: A Review of the Literature. Technical Report prepared for the UK
Intellectual Property Office and the UK Department for International
Development, Rand Europe, Cambridge, UK, 70 pp., www.rand.org/content/
dam/rand/pubs/technical_reports/2010/RAND_TR804.pdf.
Heal, G., 2009: Climate economics: a meta-review and some suggestions for future
research. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3(1), 4-21.
Heal, G., 2012: Reflections defining and measuring sustainability. Review of
Environmental Economics and Policy, 6(1), 147-163.
Heal, G. and B. Kriström, 2001: National income and the environment. Paper prepared
for inclusion in the Handbook of Environmental Economics, doi.org/10.2139/
ssrn.279112.
Heal, G. and B. Kriström, 2002: Uncertainty and climate change. Environmental and
Resource Economics, 22, 3-39.
Heltberg, R., P.B. Siegel, and S.L. Jorgensen, 2009: Addressing human vulnerability
to climate change: toward a ‘no-regrets’ approach. Global Environmental
Change, 19, 89-99.
Henriet, F., S. Hallegatte, and L. Tabourier, 2011: Firm-network characteristics and
economic robustness to natural disasters. Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 36, 150-167.
Henry, C., 1974: Option values in the economics of irreplaceable assets. The Review
of Economic Studies, 41, 89-104.
Henry, C. and M. Henry, 2002: Formalization and Applications of the Precautionary
Principles. Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper
Series No. 0102-22, 19 pp., doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1084972.
Henry, C. and J.E. Stiglitz, 2010: Intellectual property, dissemination of innovation
and sustainable development. Global Policy, 1(3), 237-251.
Hertel, T.W., A.A. Golub, A.D. Jones, M. O’Hare, R.J. Plevin, and D.M. Kammen, 2010:
Effects of US maize ethanol on global land use and greenhouse gas emissions:
estimating market-mediated responses. BioScience, 60(3), 223-231.
Hertzler, G., 2007: Adapting to climate change and managing climate risks by using
real options. Australian Journal of Agricultural Research, 58, 985-992.
Hess, U. and J. Syroka, 2005: Weather-Based Insurance in Southern Africa: The Case
of Malawi. Agriculture and Rural Development (ARD) Discussion Paper 13, The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 67 pp.
Heyward, M., 2007: Equity and international climate change negotiations: a matter
of perspective. Climate Policy, 7, 518-534.
Hochrainer, S. and R. Mechler, 2011: Natural disaster risk in Asian megacities – a
case for risk pooling? Cities, 28, 53-61.
971
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
Hochrainer, S., R. Mechler, and G. Pflug, 2009: Climate change and financial
adaptation in Africa. Investigating the impact of climate change on the
robustness of index-based microinsurance in Malawi. Mitigation and
Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, 14, 231-250, doi:10.1007/s11027-
008-9162-5.
Hof, A.F., K.C. de Bruin, R.B. Dellink, M.G.J. den Elzen, and D.P. van Vuuren, 2009: The
effect of different mitigation strategies on international financing of adaptation.
Environmental Science and Policy, 12 (7), 832-843.
Hof, A.F., D.P. van Vuuren, and M.G.J. den Elzen, 2010: A qualitative minimax regret
approach to climate change: does discounting still matter? Ecological Economics,
70(1), 43-51.
Hogarth, R. and H. Kunreuther, 1995: Decision making under ignorance: arguing with
yourself. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 10, 15-36.
Höppe, P. and E. Gurenko, 2006: Scientific and economic rationales for innovative
climate insurance solutions. Climate Policy, 6(6), 607-620.
Hourcade, J.C., P. Ambrosi, and P. Dumas, 2009: Beyond the Stern Review: lessons
from a risky venture at the limits of the cost-benefit analysis. Ecological
Economics, 68 (10), 2479-2484.
Hudgens, D. and A. Jones, 2010: Application of Ecological and Economic Models of
the Impacts of Sea-Level Rise to the Delaware Estuary. Report by Industrial
Economics, Incorporated (IEc), Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency, Climate Change Division, Climate Science Impacts Branch and
Partnership for the Delaware Estuary, IEc, Cambridge, MA, USA, 48 pp.,
www.delawareestuary.org/pdf/Climate/IEc-%20Delaware%20Estuary%
20SLAMM%20HEA%20-%20June%202010.pdf.
Hughes, G., P. Chinowsky, and K. Strzepak, 2010: The costs of adaptation to climate
change for water infrastructure in OECD countries. Utility Policy, 18(3), 142-
153.
Hunt, A. and T. Taylor, 2009: Values and cost-benefit analysis: economic efficiency in
adaptation. In: Adapting to Climate Change: Thresholds, Values, Governance
[Adger, W.N., I. Lorenzoni, and K.L. O’Brien (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, pp. 197-211.
Hunt, A. and P. Watkiss, 2011: Climate change impacts and adaption in cities: a review
of the literature. Climatic Change, 104(1), 13-49, doi:10.1007/s10584-010-
9975-6.
Hurwicz, L., 1951: Some specification problems and application to econometric
models. Econometrica, 19, 343-344.
Iglesias, A., S. Quiroga, and A. Diz, 2011: Looking into the future of agriculture in a
changing climate. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 38(3), 427-447.
IIASA, 2012: Global Energy Assessment – Toward a Sustainable Future. International
Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 1882 pp.
IMF, 2008: The Fiscal Implications of Climate Change. Fiscal Affairs Department,
International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington, DC, USA, 49 pp.
Inthorn, J., L. Kaelin, and M. Reder, 2010: Gesundheit und Gerechtigkeit. Ein
interkultureller Vergleich zwischen Österreich und den Philippinen. Schriftenreihe
Ethik und Recht in der Medizin, Springer-Verlag, Wien, Österreich, and New
York, NY, USA, 182 pp.
IPCC, 2012: Summary for Policymakers. In: Managing the Risks of Extreme Events
and Disasters to Advance Climate Change Adaptation. A Special Report of
Working Groups I and II of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
[Field, C.B., V. Barros, T.F. Stocker, D. Qin, D.J. Dokken, K.L. Ebi, M.D. Mastrandrea,
K.J. Mach, G.-K. Plattner, S.K. Allen, M. Tignor, and P.M. Midgley (eds.)].
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, pp. 1-19.
Jacoby, H., M. Rabassa, and E. Skoufias, 2011: Distributional Implications of Climate
Change in India. Policy Research Working Paper No. 5623, Poverty Reduction
and Equity Unit, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 56 pp.
Jagers, S.C. and G. Duus-Otterström, 2008: Dual climate change responsibility: on
moral divergences between mitigation and adaptation. Environmental Politics,
17, 576-591.
James, O., 2000: Regulation inside government: public interest justifications and
regulatory failures. Public Administration, 78(2), 327-334.
Janssen, R. and M. Van Herwijnen, 2006: A toolbox for multicriteria decision-making.
International Journal of Environmental Technology and Management, 6(1),
20-39.
Johnson, E.J. and G. Daniel, 2003: Do defaults save lives? Science, 302(5649), 1338-
1339.
Julius, S.H. and J.D Scheraga, 2000: The TEAM model for evaluating alternative
adaptation strategies. In: Research and Practice in Multiple Criteria Decision
Making: Proceedings of the XIV
th
International Conference on Multiple Criteria
Decision Making (MCDM), Charlottesville, VA, USA, June 8-12, 1998 [Haimes,
Y.Y. and R.E. Steuer (eds.)]. Part II, Vol. 487, Lecture Notes in Economics and
Mathematical Systems, Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg, Germany, pp. 319-330.
Kanbur, R., 2010: Macro crises and targeting transfers to the poor. In: Globalization
and Growth: Implications for a Post-Crisis World [Spence, M. and D. Leipziger
(eds.)]. The Commission on Growth and Development, The World Bank Group,
Washington, DC, USA, pp. 109-122.
Keeney, R.L. and H. Raiffa, 1993: Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences
and Value Tradeoffs. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 569 pp.
Kelly, D.L., C.D. Kolstad, and G.T. Mitchell, 2005: Adjustment costs from environmental
change. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50(3), 468-495.
Kemfert, C., 2002: An integrated assessment model of Economy-Energy-Climate
The Model Wiagem. Integrated Assessment Journal, 6(1), 75-82.
Kemfert, C., 2007: Klimawandel kostet die deutsche Volkswirtschaft Milliarden. In:
Wochenbericht. Nr. 11/2007, 74, Jahrgang/14, März 2007, Das Deutsche Institut
für Wirtschaftsforschung (DIW), DIW, Berlin, Germany, pp 165-169.
Khan, S., M.A. Khan, M.A. Hanjrab, and J. Mu, 2009: Pathways to reduce the
environmental footprints of water and energy inputs in food production. Food
Policy, 34(2), 141-149.
Kiker, G.A., T.S. Bridges, A. Varghese, T.P. Seager, and I. Linkov. 2005: Application of
multicriteria decision analysis in environmental decision making. Integrated
Environmental Assessment and Management, 1(2), 95-108.
King, J.R., 2005: Report of the Study Group on Fisheries and Ecosystem Responses
to Recent Regime Shifts. PICES Scientific Report 28, Institute of Ocean Sciences,
Secretariat, North Pacific Marine Science Organization (PICES), Sidney, BC,
Canada, 162 pp.
Kirshen, P., M. McCluskey, R. Vogel, and K. Strzepek, 2005: Global analysis of
changes in water supply yields and costs under climate change: a case study
in China. Climatic Change, 68(3), 303-330, doi:10.1007/s10584-005-1148-7.
Klein, R.J.T., 2009: Identifying countries that are particularly vulnerable to the adverse
effects of climate change: an academic or a political challenge? Carbon and
Climate Law Review, 3, 284-291.
Klein, R.J.T. and Å. Persson, 2008: Financing adaptation to climate change: issues and
priorities. In: Climate Change, European Climate Platform Reports. European
Climate Platform (ECP) Report No. 8, Research carried out in the projects ADAM
(Adaptation and Mitigation Strategies: Supporting European Climate Policy)
and Clipore (Climate Policy Research), The Centre for European Policy Studies
(CEPS), Brussels, Belgium, 18 pp., www.ceps.eu/node/1569.
Klein, R.J.T., E.L.F. Schipper, and S. Dessai, 2005: Integrating mitigation and adaptation
into climate and development policy: three research questions. Environmental
Science & Policy, 8, 579-588.
Klinsky, S. and H. Dowlatabadi, 2009: Conceptualizations of justice in climate policy.
Climate Policy, 9, 88-108.
Koetse, M. and P. Rietveld, 2012: Adaptation to climate change in the transport
sector. Transport Reviews, 32(3), 267-286.
Kok, M. and H. De Coninck, 2007: Widening the scope of policies to address climate
change: directions for mainstreaming. Environmental Science & Policy, 10, 587-
599.
Koleva, N.G., U.A. Schneider, and B.A. McCarl, 2011: Pesticide and greenhouse gas
externalities from US agriculture the impact of their internalization and
climate change. Climate Change Economics, 4(3), 1350008, doi:10.1142/
S2010007813500085.
Korteling, B., S. Dessai, and Z. Kapelan, 2013: Using information-gap decision theory
for water resources planning under severe uncertainty. Water Resources
Management, 27, 1149-1172.
Kostandini, G., B.F. Mills, S.W. Omamo, and S. Wood, 2009: Ex ante analysis of the
benefits of transgenic drought tolerance research on cereal crops in low-income
countries. Agricultural Economics, 40(4), 477-492.
Krantz, D. and H. Kunreuther, 2007: Goals and plans in decision-making. Judgment
and Decision Making, 2, 137-168.
Kreeger, D., J. Adkins, P. Cole, R. Najjar, D. Velinsky, P. Conolly, and J. Kraeuter, 2010:
Climate Change and the Delaware Estuary: Three Case Studies in Vulnerability
Assessment and Adaptation Planning. PDE Report No. 10-01, Partnership for
the Delaware Estuary, Wilmington, DE, USA, 118 pp., delawareestuary.org/pdf/
Climate/Climate%20Change%20and%20the%20Delaware%20Estuary_PDE-
10-01.pdf.
972
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Krueger, A.O., 1990: Government failures in development. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 4 (3), 9-23.
Kubal, C., D. Haase, V. Meyer, and S. Scheuer, 2009: Integrated urban flood risk
assessment – adapting a multicriteria approach to a city. Natural Hazards and
Earth System Sciences, 9(6), 1881-1895.
Kunreuther, H., 2008: Moral hazard. In: Encyclopedia of Quantitative Risk Assessment
[Melnick, E.L. and B.S. Everitt (eds.)]. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, UK,
doi:10.1002/9780470061596.risk0655.
Kunreuther, H. and R. Roth, 1998: Paying the Price: The Status and Role of Insurance
Against Natural Disasters in the United States. 1
st
edn., Joseph Henry Press,
Washington, DC, USA, 320 pp.
Kunreuther, H., R. Ginsberg, L. Miller, P. Sagi, P. Slovic, B. Borkan, and N. Katz, 1978:
Disaster Insurance Protection: Public Policy Lessons. John Wiley & Sons Canada,
Ltd., Mississauga, ON, Canada, 400 pp.
Kunreuther, H., R. Meyer, and E. Michel-Kerjan, 2009: Overcoming decision biases
to reduce losses from natural catastrophes. In: The Behavioral Foundations of
Public Policy [Shafir, E. (ed.)]. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, USA and
Woodstock, UK, pp. 398-414.
Kunreuther, H., G. Heal, M. Allen, O. Edenhofer, C.B. Field, and G. Yohe, 2013: Risk
management and climate change. Nature Climate Change, 3, 447-450.
Laffont, J.J., 1995: Regulation, moral hazard and insurance of environmental risks.
Journal of Public Economics, 58(3), 319-336.
Lall S.V. and U. Deichmann, 2010: Density and Disasters: Economics of Urban Hazard
Risk. Policy Research Working Paper 5161, the Finance, Economics, and Urban
Development Department and the Environment and Energy Team, Development
Research Group, The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
/ The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 48 pp.
Larsen, P.H., S. Goldsmith, O. Smith, M.L. Wilson, K. Strzepek, P. Chinowsky, and B.
Saylor, 2008: Estimating future costs for Alaska public infrastructure at risk
from climate change. Global Environmental Change, 18(3), 442-457.
Layton, D. and G. Brown, 2000: Heterogeneous preferences regarding global climate
change. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(4), 616-624.
Leary, N., J. Adejuwon, V. Barros, I. Burton, J. Kukarni, and R. Lasco (eds.), 2008:
Climate Change and Adaptation. Earthscan, London, UK and Sterling, VA, USA,
381 pp.
Lecocq, F. and Z. Shalizi, 2007: Balancing Expenditures on Mitigation of and
Adaptation to Climate Change: An Exploration of Issues Relevant to Developing
Countries. Policy Research Working Paper No. 4299, the Sustainable Rural and
Urban Development Team, Development Research Group, The International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC,
USA, 48 pp.
Lemieux, C.J., and D.J. Scott, 2005: Climate change, biodiversity conservation and
protected area planning in Canada. Canadian Geographer / Le Géographecanadien,
49(4), 384-397.
Lempert, R.J. and M.T. Collins, 2007: Managing the risk of uncertain thresholds
responses: comparison of robust, optimum, and precautionary approaches. Risk
Analysis, 27, 1009-1026.
Lempert, R. and D.G. Groves, 2010: Identifying and evaluating robust adaptive policy
responses to climate change for water management agencies in the American
west. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 77, 960-974.
Lempert, R. and N. Kalra, 2009: Managing Climate Risks in Developing Countries
with Robust Decision Making. World Resources Report, World Resources Institute
(WRI), Washington, DC, USA.
Lempert, R.J. and N. Kalra, 2011: Managing Climate Risks in Developing Countries with
Robust Decision Making. World Resources Institute (WRI) Report, Washington,
DC, USA, 9 pp., www.wri.org/sites/default/files/uploads/wrr_lempert_and_
kalra_uncertainty_.pdf.
Lempert, R.J. and M.E. Schlesinger, 2000: Robust strategies for abating climate
change. Climatic Change, 45(3-4), 387-401.
Lempert, R.J., D.G. Groves, S.W. Popper, and S.C. Bankes, 2006: A general, analytic
method for generating robust strategies and narrative scenarios. Management
Science, 52(4), 514-528.
Lempert, R., N. Kalra, S. Peyraud, Z. Mao, S.B. Tan, D. Cira, and A. Lotsch, 2013:
Ensuring Robust Flood Risk Management in Ho Chi Minh City. Policy Research
Working Paper No. 6465, the Office of the Chief Economist, Sustainable
Development Network, The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 63 pp.
Lesser, W., 2007: Chapter 4.5: Plant breeders’ rights: an introduction. In: Intellectual
Property Management in Health and Agricultural Innovations: A Handbook of
Best Practices [ Krattiger, A., R.T. Mahoney, L. Nelsen, J.A. Thomson, A.B.
Bennett, K. Satyanarayana, G.D. Graff, C. Fernandez, and S.P. Kowalski (eds.)].
Vol. 2, Centre for the Management of Intellectual Property in Health Research
and Development (MIHR), Oxford Centre for Innovation, Oxford, UK and Public
Intellectual Property Resource for Agriculture (PIPRA), Davis, CA, USA, pp. 381-388.
Létard, V., H. Flandre, S. Lepeltier, 2004: La France et les Français Face à la Canicule:
les Leçons d’une Crise. Rapport d’information du Sénat no 195, Session
Ordinaire de 2003-2004, Annexe au procès-verbal de la séance du 3 vrier
2004, 391 pp., www.senat.fr/rap/r03-195/r03-1951.pdf (in French).
Levine, M.E. and J.L. Forrence, 1990: Regulatory capture, public interest, and the
public agenda: toward a synthesis. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization,
6, 167-198.
Lichtenberg, E. and R. Smith-Ramírez, 2011: Slippage in conservation cost sharing.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 93(1), 113-129.
Linnerooth-Bayer, J., R. Mechler, and G. Pflug, 2005: Refocusing disaster aid. Science,
309, 1044-1046.
Linnerooth-Bayer, J., S. Hochrainer, and R. Mechler, 2011: Insurance against losses
from natural disasters in developing countries: evidence, gaps and the way
forward. Journal of Integrated Disaster Risk Management, 1(1), doi:10.5595/
idrim.2011.0013.
Linquiti, P. and N. Vonortas, 2012: The value of flexibility in adapting to climate
change: a real options analysis of investments in coastal defense. Climate
Change Economics, 3(2), 1250008, doi:10.1142/S201000781250008X.
Loomis, J., P. Kent, L. Strange, K. Fausch, and A. Covich, 2000: Measuring the total
economic value of restoring ecosystem services in an impaired river basin:
results from a contingent valuation survey. Ecological Economics, 33, 103-117.
Lucena, A.F.P., R. Schaeffer, and A.S. Szklo, 2010: Least cost-adaptation options for
global climate change impacts on the Brazilian electric power system. Global
Environmental Change, 20(2), 342-350.
Magat, W., K.W. Viscusi, and J. Huber, 1987: Risk-dollar tradeoffs, risk perceptions,
and consumer behaviour. In: Learning About Risk [Viscusi, W. and W. Magat
(eds.)]. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, USA, pp. 83-97.
Margulis, S., C. Dubeux, and J. Marcovitch (coords.), 2011: The Economics of Climate
Change in Brazil: Costs and Opportunities. Faculty of Economics, Business and
Accounting of the University of São Paulo (FEAUSP), School of Economics,
Business Administration and Accountancy, University of São Paulo, São Paulo,
Brazil, 81 pp.
Markandya, A. and A. Chiabai, 2009: Valuing climate change impacts on human
health: empirical evidence from the literature, International Journal of
Environmental Research and Public Health, 6, 759-786.
Markandya, A. and A. Mishra (eds.), 2011: Costing Adaptation: Preparing for Climate
Change in India. The Energy and Resources Institute (TERI), TERI Press, New
Delhi, India, 258 pp.
Markandya, A. and P. Nunes, 2012: Is the value of bioprospecting contracts too low?
International Journal of Ecological Economics and Statistics, 26(3), 67-82.
Martinez-Alier, J., G. Munda, and J. O’Neill, 1998: Weak comparability of values as
a foundation for ecological economics. Ecological Economics, 26, 277-286.
Mathew, S., S. Truck, and A. Hendersen-Sellers, 2012: Kochi, India case study of
climate change adaptation to floods: ranking government investment options.
Global Environmental Change, 22, 308-319.
Matrosov, E.S., S. Padula, and J.J. Harou, 2013: Selecting portfolios of water supply
and demand management strategies under uncertainty contrasting economic
optimisation and ‘robust decision making’ approaches. Water Resources
Management, 27, 1123-1148.
Matthews, S., R. O’Connor, and A.J. Plantinga, 2002: Quantifying the impacts on
biodiversity of policies for carbon sequestration in forests. Ecological Economics,
40(1), 71-87.
McCann, L. and K.W. Easter, 2000: Transaction costs of policies to reduce agricultural
phosphorous in the Minnesota river. Land Economics, 75 (3), 402-414.
McGray, H., A. Hammill, R. Bradley, E.L. Schipper, and J.-E. Parry, 2007: Weathering
the Storm: Options for Framing Adaptation and Development. World Resources
Institute, Washington, DC, USA, 57 pp.
McKinley, D.C., M.G. Ryan, R.A. Birdsey, C.P. Giardina, M.E. Harmon, L.S. Heath, R.A.
Houghton, R.B. Jackson, J.F. Morrison, B.C. Murray, D.E. Pataki, and K.E. Skog,
2011: A synthesis of current knowledge on forests and carbon storage in the
United States. Ecological Applications, 21, 1902-1924.
McMichael, A.J., D. Campbell-Lendrum, S. Kovats, S. Edwards, P. Wilkinson, T. Wilson,
R. Nicholls, S. Hales, F. Tanser, D. LeSueur, M. Schlesinger, and N. Andronova,
2004: Global climate change. In: Comparative Quantification of Health Risks:
973
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
Global and Regional Burden of Disease due to Selected Major Risk Factors
[Ezzati, M., A. Lopez, A. Rodgers, and C. Murray (eds.)]. World Health Organization
(WHO), Geneva, Switzerland, pp. 1543-1649.
Mearns, R. and A. Norton (eds.), 2010: Social Dimensions of Climate Change: Equity
and Vulnerability in a Warming World. The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 319 pp.
Medellín-Azuara, J., J. Harou, M. Olivares, K. Madani, J. Lund, R. Howitt, S. Tanaka,
M. Jenkins, and T. Zhu, 2008: Adaptability and adaptations of California’s water
supply system to dry climate warming. Climatic Change, 87(Suppl. 1), S75-S90.
Mendelsohn, R., 2000: Efficient adaptation to climate change. Climatic Change, 45,
583-600.
Mendelsohn, R. and M. Balick, 1995: The value of undiscovered pharmaceuticals in
tropical forests. Economic Botany, 49(2), 223-228.
Mendelsohn, R. and A. Dinar, 2003: Climate, water, and agriculture. Land Economics,
79(3), 328-341.
Mendelsohn, R. and J. Neumann (eds.), 1999: The Impact of Climate Change on the
US Economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 344 pp.
Mendelsohn, R., W.D. Nordhaus, and D. Shaw, 1994: The impact of global warming
on agriculture: a Ricardian analysis. The American Economic Review, 84(4),
753-771.
Mendelsohn, R., A. Dinar, and L. Williams, 2006: The distributional impact of climate
change on rich and poor countries. Environment and Development Economics,
11(02), 159-178, doi:10.1017/S1355770X05002755.
Mendelsohn, R., K. Emanuel, S. Chonabayashi, and L. Bakkensen, 2012: The impact
of climate change on global tropical cyclone damage. Nature Climate Change,
2, 205-209, doi:10.1038/NCLIMATE1357.
Mercer, J., I. Kelman, K., Lloyd, and S. Suchet-Pearson, 2008: Reflections on use of
participatory research for disaster risk reduction. Area, 40(2), 172-183.
Michel-Kerjan, E., 2006: Disasters and public policy: can market lessons help address
government failures. In: 2006 Ninety Ninth Annual Conference: NTA Proceedings
from the 99th Annual Conference in Boston MA. National Tax Association
(NTA), Washington, DC, USA, pp. 179-187, www.ntanet.org/publications/nta-
proceedings/122.html.
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, 2005: Ecosystems and Human Well-Being:
Synthesis. Island Press, Washington, DC, USA, 137 pp.
Miller, D., 2007: National Responsibility and Global Justice. Oxford University Press,
Oxford, UK and New York, NY, USA, 298 pp.
Millner, A., S. Dietz, and G. Heal, 2010: Ambiguity and Climate Policy. NBER Working
Paper No. 16050, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge,
MA, USA, 29 pp., www.nber.org/papers/w16050.pdf.
Ministry for Land Management, Tourism and Environment, 2007: National
Adaptation Plan of Action (NAPA). Ministry for Land Management, Tourism and
Environment, Burundi, Republic of Burundi, Bujumbura, Burundi, 74 pp.
Moser, S.C. and J.A. Ekstrom, 2010: A framework to diagnose barriers to climate
change adaptation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the
United States of America, 107(51), 22026-22031.
Mote, P.W., E.A. Parson, A.F. Hamlet, K.N. Ideker, W.S. Keeton, D.P. Lettenmaier, N.J.
Mantua, E.L. Miles, D.W. Peterson, D.L. Peterson, R. Slaughter, and A.K. Snover,
2003: Preparing for climatic change: the water, salmon, and forests of the
Pacific Northwest, Climatic Change, 61(1), 45-88.
Mu, J. and B.A. McCarl, 2011: Adaptation to Climate Change: Land Use and Livestock
Management in the U.S. Selected paper presented at the 2011 Annual Meeting
of the Southern Agricultural Economics Association, Corpus Christi, TX, February,
2011, 35 pp., ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/98708/2/Climate_change_
and_livestock_management_2011_%5B3%5Dx.pdf.
Mu, J., B.A. McCarl, and A.M. Wein, 2012: Adaptation to climate change: changes in
farmland use and stocking rate in the U.S. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies
for Global Change, 18, 713-730, doi:10.1007/s11027-012-9384-4.
Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres, and J. Braña Varela, 2008: Paying for the
hydrological services of Mexico’s forests: analysis, negotiations and results.
Ecological Economics, 65, 725-736.
Muradian, R., E. Corbera, U. Pascual, N. Kosoy, and P. May, 2010: Reconciling theory
and practice: an alternative conceptual framework for understanding payments
for environmental services. Ecological Economics, 69, 1202-1208.
Musgrave, R.A. and P.B. Musgrave, 1973: Public Finance in Theory and Practice.
McGraw Hill, Inc., US, New York, NY, USA, 650 pp.
Naseem, A., D.J. Spielman, and S.W. Omamo, 2010: Private-sector investment in
R&D: a review of policy options to promote its growth in developing-country
agriculture. Agribusiness, 26, 143-173.
Navrud, S. and R. Ready, 2007: Environmental Value Transfer: Issues and Methods.
The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources Series, Book 9, Springer,
Dordrecht, Netherlands, 290 pp.
National Research Council, 2005: Valuing Ecosystem Services: Toward Better
Environmental Decision-Making. Committee on Assessing and Valuing the
Services of Aquatic and Related Terrestrial Ecosystems, National Research
Council, National Academies Press, Washington, DC, USA, 263 pp.
National Research Council, 2010: Adapting to the Impacts of Climate Change.
America’s Climate Choices: Panel on Adapting to the Impacts of Climate
Change, Division on Earth and Life Studies, National Research Council, The
National Academies Press, Washington, DC, USA, 272 pp.
New, M. and M. Hulme, 2000: Representing uncertainty in climate change scenarios:
a Monte-Carlo approach. Integrated Assessment, 1(3), 203-213.
Nicholls, R. and R. Tol, 2006: Impacts and responses to sea level rise: a global analysis
of the SRES scenarios over the twenty-first century. Philosophical Transactions
of the Royal Society A, 364, 1073-1095.
Nielsen, J.O. and A. Reenberg, 2010: Cultural barriers to climate change adaptation:
a case study from Northern Burkina Faso. Global Environmental Change, 20,
142-152.
Nordhaus, W., 2006: The Economics of Hurricanes in the United States. NBER
Working Paper No.12813, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER),
Cambridge, MA, USA, 46 pp.
Nordhaus, W.D., 2008: A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global
Warming Policies. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT, USA and London, UK,
234 pp.
NRTEE, 2012: Facing the Elements: Building Business Resilience in a Changing
Climate. Advisory Report, National Round Table on the Environment and the
Economy (NRTEE), Ottawa, ON, Canada, 131 pp., collectionscanada.gc.ca/
webarchives2/20130322175153/http://nrtee-trnee.ca/wp-content/uploads/
2012/04/cp5-advisory-report.pdf.
O’Brien, K.L., R. Leichenko, U. Kelkar, H. Venema, G. Aandahl, H. Tompkins, A. Javed,
S. Bhadwal, S. Barg, L. Nygaard, and J. West, 2004: Mapping vulnerability to
multiple stressors: climate change and globalization in India. Global
Environmental Change, 14, 303-313.
O’Brien, K., B. Hayward, and F. Berkes, 2009: Rethinking social contracts: building
resilience in a changing climate. Ecology and Society, 14(2), 12, www.ecology
andsociety.org/vol14/iss2/art12/.
O’Brien, K., A. St. Clair, and B. Kristoffersen, 2010: The framing of climate change:
why it matters. In: Climate Change, Ethics and Human Security [O’Brien, K., A.
St. Clair and B. Kristoffersen (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
UK, pp. 3-22.
O’Brien, K., M. Pelling, A. Patwardhan, S. Hallegatte, A. Maskrey, T. Oki, U. Oswald-
Spring, T. Wilbanks, and P.Z. Yanda, 2012: Toward a sustainable and resilient
future. In: Managing the Risks of Extreme Events and Disasters to Advance
Climate Change Adaptation. A Special Report of Working Groups I and II of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Field, C.B., V. Barros, T.F. Stocker,
D. Qin, D.J. Dokken, K.L. Ebi, M.D. Mastrandrea, K.J. Mach, G.-K. Plattner, S.K.
Allen, M. Tignor, and P.M. Midgley (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, pp. 437-486.
O’Hara, J. and K. Georgakakos, 2008: Quantifying the urban water supply impacts
of climate change. Water Resources Management, 22, 1477-1497.
Olmstead, S.M., 2010: The economics of managing scarce water resources. Review
of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4(2), 179-198.
Osberghaus, D., A. Dannenberg, T. Mennel, and B. Sturm, 2010a: The role of the
government in adaptation to climate change. Environment and Planning C:
Government and Policy, 28(5), 834-850.
Osberghaus, D., E. Finkerl, and M. Pohl, 2010b: Individual Adaptation to Climate
Change: The Role of Information and Perceived Risk. ZEW Discussion Paper
No. 10-061, Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung (ZEW) GmbH,
Centre for European Economic Research, Mannheim, Germany, 31 pp.,
ftp://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp10061.pdf.
Owour, B., W. Mauta, and S. Eriksen, 2011: Strengthening sustainable adaptation:
examining interactions between pastoral and agropastoral groups in dryland
Kenya. Climate and Development, 3(1), 42-58.
Oxfam, 2007: Adapting to Climate Change: What’s Needed in Poor Countries, and
Who Should Pay. Oxfam Briefing Paper No. 104, Oxfam International
Secretariat, Oxford, UK, 47 pp.
Paavola, J. and W.N. Adger, 2006: Fair adaptation to climate change. Ecological
Economics, 56, 594-609.
974
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Pagiola, S., 2008: Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica. Ecological
Economics, 65(4), 712-724.
Pahl-Wostl, C., 2009: A conceptual framework for analysing adaptive capacity and
multi-level learning processes in resource governance regimes. Global
Environmental Change, 19, 354-365.
Pal, S., 2011: Impacts of CGIAR crop improvement and natural resource management
research: a review of evidence. Agricultural Economics Research Review, 24,
185-200.
Panayotou, T., J.D. Sachs, and A.P. Zwane, 2002: Compensation for ‘meaningful
participation’ in climate change control: a modest proposal and empirical
analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(3), 437-
454, doi:10.1006/jeem.2001.1189.
Parry, M., N. Arnell, P. Berry, D. Dodman, S. Fankhauser, C. Hope, S. Kovats, R. Nichollas,
D. Satterthwaite, R. Tiffin, and R. Wheeler, 2009: Assessing the Costs of
Adaptation to Climate Change: A Review of the UNFCCC and Other Recent
Estimates. International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED) and
Grantham Institute for Climate Change, Imperial College London, London, UK,
111 pp.
Patt, A.G. and D. Schröter, 2008: Perceptions of climate risk in Mozambique: implications
for the success of adaptation strategies. Global Environmental Change, 18,
458-467.
Patt, A.G., D.P. van Vuuren, F. Berkhout, A. Aaheim, A.F. Hof, M. Isaac, and R. Mechler,
2009: Adaptation in integrated assessment modeling: where do we stand?
Climate Change, 99, 383-402, doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9687-y.
Patz, J.A., H.K. Gibbs, J.A. Foley, J.V. Rogers, and K.R. Smith, 2007: Climate change
and global health: quantifying a growing ethical crisis. EcoHealth, 4(4), 397-
405.
Pelling, M. and K. Dill, 2009: Disaster politics: tipping points for change in the
adaptation of socio-political regimes. Progress in Human Geography, 34, 21-
37, doi:10.1177/0309132509105004.
Pelling, M., C. High, J. Dearing, and D. Smith, 2007: Shadow spaces for social learning:
a relational understanding of adaptive capacity to climate change within
organizations. Environment and Planning A, 40(4), 867-884.
Pendleton, L., P. King, C. Mohn, D.G. Webster, R.K. Vaughn, and P. Adams, 2008:
Estimating the Potential Economic Impacts of Climate Change on Southern
California Beaches. CEC-500-2009-033-D, Paper prepared by the California
Climate Change Center as the result of work sponsored by the California Energy
Commission (Energy Commission) and the California Environmental Protection
Agency (Cal/EPA), 104 pp., www.energy.ca.gov/2009publications/CEC-500-
2009-033/CEC-500-2009-033-D.PDF.
Persson, Å., R.J.T. Klein, C. Kehler Siebert, A. Atteridge, B. Müller, J. Hoffmaister, M.
Lazarus, and T. Takama, 2009: Adaptation Finance under a Copenhagen Agreed
Outcome. Research Report, Stockholm Environment Institute (SEI), Stockholm,
Sweden, 187 pp. www.sei-international.org/mediamanager/documents/
Publications/SEI-ResearchReport-PerssonA-AdaptationFinanceUnderA
CopenhagenAgreedOutcome-2009.pdf.
Peters, E. and P. Slovic, 1996: The role of affect and worldviews as orienting
dispositions in the perception and acceptance of nuclear power. Journal of
Applied Social Psychology, 26(16), 1427-1453.
Peterson, J.M. and Y. Ding, 2005: Economic adjustments to groundwater depletion
in the high plains: do water-saving irrigation systems save water? American
Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(1), 147-159.
Pfeiffer, L. and C.Y. Lin, 2010: The effect of irrigation technology on groundwater
use. Choices, 3
rd
Quarter, 25(3), www.choicesmagazine.org/magazine/pdf/
article_147.pdf.
Pielke, R., Jr., 2007: Mistreatment of the economic impacts of extreme events in the
Stern Review Report on the Economics of Climate Change. Global Environmental
Change, 17(4), 302-310.
Plantinga, A.J. and J. Wu, 2003: Co-benefits from carbon sequestration in forests:
evaluating reductions in agricultural externalities from and afforestation policy
in Wisconsin. Land Economics, 79(1), 74-85.
Platt, R.H., 1999: Disasters and Democracy: The Politics of Extreme Natural Events.
Island Press, Washington, DC, USA, 320 pp.
Podsakoff, P.M., S.B. MacKenzie, R.H. Moorman, and R. Fetter, 1990: Transformational
leader behaviors and their effects on followers’ trust in leader, satisfaction, and
organizational citizenship behaviors. Leadership Quarterly, 1(2), 107-142.
Popp, D., 2004: R&D Subsidies and Climate Policy: is there a “Free Lunch”? NBER
Working Paper No. 10880, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER),
Cambridge, MA, USA, 36 pp.
Porras, I., M. Grieg-Gran, and N. Neves, 2008: All that Glitters: A Review of Payments
for Watershed Services in Developing Countries. IIED Natural Resource Issues
11, International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London,
UK, 129 pp.
Portney, P.R. and J. Mullahy, 1986: Urban air quality and acute respiratory illness.
Journal of Urban Economics, 20, 21-38.
Purvis, M., P. Bares, and C. Hayes, 2008: A probabilistic methodology to estimate
future coastal flood risk due to sea level rise. Coastal Engineering, 55(12),
1062-1073.
Qin, X.S., G.H. Huang, A. Chakma, X.H. Nie, and Q.G. Lin, 2008: A MCDM-based expert
system for climate-change impact assessment and adaptation planning a
case study for the Georgia Basin, Canada. Expert Systems with Applications,
34(3), 2164-2179.
Ranger, N., A. Millner, S. Dietz, S. Fankhauser, A. Lopez, and G. Ruta, 2010: Adaptation
in the UK: A Decision-Making Process. Policy Brief, Grantham Research Institute
on Climate Change and the Environment and Center for Climate Change
Economics and Policy, the London School of Economics and Political Science,
London, UK, 61 pp., www.cccep.ac.uk/Publications/Policy/docs/PB-adaptation
UK-ranger.pdf.
Ranger, N., S. Hallegatte, S. Bhattacharya, M. Bachu, S. Priya, K. Dhore, F. Rafique, P.
Mathur, N. Naville, F. Henriet, C. Herweijer, S. Pohit, and J. Corfee-Morlot, 2011:
A preliminary assessment of the potential impact of climate change on flood
risk in Mumbai, Climatic Change, 104(1), 139-167.
Rao, K. and U. Hess, 2009: Scaling up in India: the public sector. In: Index Insurance
and Climate Risk: Prospects for Development and Disaster Management
[Hellmuth, M.E., D.E. Osgood, U. Hess, A. Moorhead, and H. Bhojwani (eds.)].
Climate and Society No. 2, International Research Institute for Climate and
Society (IRI), New York, NY, USA, pp. 87-89.
Reeder, T., J. Wicks, L. Lovell, and O. Tarrant, 2009: Protecting London from tidal
flooding: limits to engineering adaptation. In: Adapting to Climate Change:
Thresholds, Values, Governance [Adger, W.N., I. Lorenzoni, and K. O’Brien (eds.)].
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 54-78.
Refsgaard, J.C., K. Arnbjerg-Nielsen, M. Drews, K. Halsnæs, E. Jeppesen, H. Madsen,
A. Markandya, J.E. Olesen, J.R. Porter, and J.H. Christensen, 2013: The role of
uncertainty in climate change adaptation strategies a Danish water
management example. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global
Change, 18(3), 337-359.
Repetto, R., 2008: The Climate Crisis and the Adaptation Myth. Working Paper 13,
Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, New Haven, CT, USA, 20 pp.
Ribaudo, M.O., 1989: Water Quality Benefits from the Conservation Reserve Program.
Agricultural Economic Report, Vol. 606, U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Economic Research Service, Washington, DC, USA, 30 pp.
Rosenzweig, C., K.M. Strzepek, D.C. Major, A. Iglesias, D.N. Yates, A. McCluskey, and
D. Hillel, 2004: Water resources for agriculture in a changing climate:
international case studies. Global Environmental Change, 14, 345-360.
Rosenzweig, C., W.D. Solecki, L. Parshall, B. Lynn, J. Cox, R. Goldberg, S. Hodges, S.
Gaffin, R.B. Slosberg, P. Savio, F. Dunstan, and M. Watson, 2009: Mitigating New
York City’s heat island: integrating stakeholder perspectives and scientific
evaluation. Bulletin of the American Meteorological Society, 90(9), 1297-1312.
Roy, J., 2000: The rebound effect: some empirical evidence from India. Energy Policy,
28(6-7), 433-438.
Saleth, R.M., A. Dinar, and J.A. Frisbie, 2012: Climate change, drought, and agriculture:
the role of effective institutions and infrastructure. In: Handbook on Climate
Change and Agriculture [Dinar, A. and R. Mendelsohn (eds.)]. Edward Elgar:
Cheltenham, UK, pp. 466-485.
Samet, J.M., 2010: Public Health: Adapting to Climate Change. Issue Brief 10-06,
Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, USA, 13 pp., www.rff.org/RFF/
Documents/RFF-IB-10-06.pdf.
Samuelson, P.A., 1954: The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics
and Statistics, 36(4), 387-389.
Sartori, I. and A.G. Hestnes, 2007: Energy use in the life cycle of conventional and
low-energy 30 buildings: a review article. Energy & Buildings, 39(3), 249-257.
Savage, L.J., 1951: The theory of statistical decisions. Journal of the American
Statistical Association, 46(253), 55-67.
Schalatek, L., S. Nakhooda, S. Barnard, and A. Caravani, 2012: Climate Finance
Thematic Briefing: Adaptation Finance. Overseas Development Institute (ODI),
London, UK and Heinrich Böll Stiftung North America, Washington, DC, USA, 2 pp.
Schelling, T., 1992: Some economics of global warming. American Economic Review,
82(1), 1-14.
975
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
Schelling, T., 1997: The cost of combating global warming: facing the tradeoffs.
Foreign Affairs, 76(6), 8-14.
Schlenker, W. and D.B Lobell, 2010: Robust negative impacts of climate change on
African agriculture. Environmental Research Letters, 5(1), 014010, doi:10.1088/
1748-9326/5/1/014010.
Schlenker, W. and M.J. Roberts, 2009: Nonlinear temperature effects indicate
severe damages to U.S. crop yields under climate change. Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 106(37), 15594-
15598.
Schlenker, W., M. Hanemann, and A. Fisher, 2005: Will US agriculture really benefit
from global warming? Accounting for irrigation in the hedonic approach.
American Economic Review, 95(1), 395-406.
Schlenker, W., W.M. Hanemann, and A.C. Fisher, 2006: The impact of global warming
on U.S. agriculture: an econometric analysis of optimal growing conditions,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(1), 113-125.
Schultz, K., 2012: Financing climate adaptation with a credit mechanism: initial
considerations, Climate Policy, 12(2), 187-197.
Schwartz, P., 1996: The Art of the Long View. Double Day, New York, NY, USA,
272 pp.
Scott, D.J., C.J. Lemieux, and L. Malone, 2011: Climate services to support sustainable
tourism and adaptation to climate change. Climate Research, 47(1), 111-122,
doi:10.3354/cr00952.
SEGCC, 2007: Confronting Climate Change: Avoiding the Unmanageable and
Managing the Unavoidable [Bierbaum, R.M., J.P. Holdren, M.C. MacCracken,
R.H. Moss, and P.H. Raven (eds.)]. Report prepared for the 15th Session of the
United Nations Commission on Sustainable Development by the United
Nations-Sigma XI Scientific Expert Group on Climate Change (SEGCC), Sigma
Xi, Research Triangle Park, NC, USA and United Nations Foundation, Washington,
DC, USA, 144 pp., www.sigmaxi.org/programs/unseg/Full_Report.pdf.
Seo, S.N. and R. Mendelsohn, 2008a: An analysis of crop choice: adapting to climate
change in South American farms. Ecological Economics, 67(1), 109-116.
Seo, S.N. and R. Mendelsohn, 2008b: Animal husbandry in Africa: climate change
impacts and adaptations. African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,
2(1), 65-82.
Seo, S.N. and R. Mendelsohn, 2008c: Measuring impacts and adaptations to climate
change: a structural Ricardian model of African livestock management.
Agricultural Economics, 38(2), 151-165.
Seo, S., R. Mendelsohn, A. Dinar, R. Hassan, and P. Kurukulasuriya, 2009a: A Ricardian
analysis of the distribution of climate change impacts on agriculture across
agro-ecological zones in Africa. Environmental and Resource Economics, 43(3),
313-332.
Seo, S.N., R. Mendelsohn, A. Dinar, and P. Kurukulasuriya, 2009b: Adapting to climate
change mosaically: an analysis of African livestock management by agro-
ecological zones. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 9(2), 1-35,
doi:10.2202/1935-1682.1955.
Shogren, J. and L. Taylor, 2008: On behavioral environmental economics. Review of
Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(1), 26-44.
Skees, J.R., B.J. Barnett, and A.G. Murphy, 2008: Creating insurance markets for natural
disaster risk in lower income countries: the potential role for securitization.
Agricultural Finance Review, 68, 151-157.
Slovic, P., 1987: Perception of risk. Science, 236, 280-285.
Smit, B. and J. Wandel, 2006: Adaptation, adaptive capacity and vulnerability. Global
Environmental Change, 16(3), 282-292.
Smit, B., I. Burton, R. Klein, and J. Wandel, 2000: An anatomy of adaptation to climate
change and variability. Climatic Change, 45, 223-251.
Smith, J.B. and S.S. Lenhart, 1996: Climate change adaptation policy options. Climate
Research, 6, 193-201.
Sohngen, B., R. Mendelsohn, and R. Sedjo, 2001: A global model of climate change
impacts on timber markets. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,
26(2), 326-343.
Sperling, F., C. Valdivia, R. Quiroz, R. Valdivia, L. Angulo, A. Seimon, and I. Noble,
2008: Transitioning to Climate Resilient Development: Perspectives from
Communities in Peru. World Bank Environment Department Papers, Paper No.
115, Climate Change Series, The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 103 pp.
Spittlehouse, D.L. and R.B. Stewart, 2003: Adaptation to climate change in forest
management. BC Journal of Ecosystems and Management, 4 (1), 1-11.
Squire, L. and H.G. van der Tack, 1975: Economic Analysis of Projects. The World Bank
Publications, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD, USA, 104 pp.
Srinivasan, U.T., S.P. Carey, E. Hallstein, P.A.T. Higgins, A.C. Kerr, L.E. Koteen, A.B.
Smith, R. Watson, J. Harte, and R.B. Norgaard, 2008: The debt of nations and
the distribution of ecological impacts from human activities. Proceedings of
the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 105(5),
1768- 1773.
Stafford-Smith, M., L. Horrocks, A. Harvey, and C. Hamilton, 2011: Rethinking
adaptation for a 4
°
C world. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A,
369, 196-216.
Starret, D.A., 1988: Foundations in Public Economics. Cambridge University Press,
New York, NY, USA, 315 pp.
Stavins, R.N., 1995: Transaction costs and tradeable permits. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 29(2), 133-148.
Stern, N., 2006: Stern Review: Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK, 692 pp.
Sterner, T., 2002: Policy Instruments for Environmental and Natural Resource
Management. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, USA, 503 pp.
Sterner, T. (ed.), 2011: Fuel Taxes and the Poor: The Distributional Effects of Gasoline
Taxation and Their Implications for Climate Policy. RFF Press, Abingdon, UK and
New York, NY, USA, 357 pp.
Sterner, T. and M. Persson, 2007: An Even Sterner Review: Introducing Relative Prices
into the Discounting Debate. Resources for Future Discussion Paper RFF DP
07-37 July 2007, Washington, DC, USA, 21 pp.
Suarez, P. and A.G. Patt, 2004: Cognition, caution, and credibility: the risks of climate
forecast application. Risk Decision and Policy, 9(1), 75-89.
Suarez, P., W. Anderson, V. Mahal, and T.R. Lakshmanan, 2005: Impacts of flooding
and climate change on urban transportation: a system-wide performance
assessment of the Boston Metro Area. Transportation Research Part D: Transport
and Environment, 10(3), 231-244.
Surminski, S., 2010: Adapting to the Extreme Weather Impacts of Climate Change
How Can the Insurance Industry Help? ClimateWise Secretariat, London, UK,
43 pp.
Sutton, W., J. Srivastava, and J. Neumann, 2013: Looking Beyond the Horizon: How
Climate Change Impacts and Adaptation Responses Will Reshape Agriculture
in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 177 pp.
Swiss Re, 1998: Floods An Insurable Risk? A Market Survey. Risk Perception Report,
Swiss Reinsurance Company (Swiss Re), Zurich, Switzerland, 51 pp.
Tacconi, L., 2012: Redefining payments for environmental services. Ecological
Economics, 73, 29-36.
Tebaldi, C., R. Smith, D. Nychka, and L. Mearns, 2005: Quantifying uncertainty in
projections of regional climate change: a Bayesian approach to the analysis of
multi-model ensembles. Journal of Climate, 18, 1524-1540.
TEEB, 2010: The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Mainstreaming the
Economics of Nature : A Synthesis of the Approach, Conclusions and
Recommendations of TEEB. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity
(TEEB) hosted by the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), UNEP
TEEB, Geneva, Switzerland, 36 pp.
Thaler, R., 1999: Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,
12, 183-206.
Tierney, K.J., 1995: Impacts of Recent U.S. Disasters on Businesses: The 1993 Midwest
Floods and the 1994 Northridge Earthquake. Paper presented at the National
Center for Earthquake Engineering Research Conference: “Economic Impacts
of Catastrophic Earthquakes – Anticipating the Unexpected,” New York, NY,
September 12-13, 1995, Disaster Research Center, University of Delaware,
Newark, DE, USA, 53 pp.
Tol, R.S.J., 1996: The damage costs of climate change towards a dynamic
representation. Ecological Economics, 19(1) 67-90.
Tol, R.S.J., 2005: Emission abatement versus development as strategies to reduce
vulnerability to climate change: an application of FUND. Environment and
Development Economics, 10(5), 615-629.
Tol, R.S.J. and G.W. Yohe, 2007: The weakest link hypothesis for adaptive capacity:
an empirical test. Global Environmental Change, 17, 218-227.
Tol, R.S.J., S. Fankhauser, and J.B. Smith, 1998: The scope for adaptation to climate
change: what can we learn from the impact literature? Global Environmental
Change, 8(2), 109-123.
Tol, R.S.J., T.E. Downing, O.J. Kuik, and J.B. Smith, 2004: Distributional aspects of
climate change impacts. Global Environmental Change, 14, 259-272.
Train, K., 1985: Discount rates in consumer’s energy-related decisions: a review of
the literature. Energy, 10(12), 1243-1253.
976
Chapter 17 Economics of Adaptation
17
Transportation Research Board, 2008: Potential Impacts of Climate Change on
U.S. Transportation. Transportation Research Board Special Report 290,
Committee on Climate Change and U.S. Transportation, Division on Earth and
Life Studies, National Research Council, the National Academies Press,
Washington, DC, USA, 280 pp.
Trenberth, K.E., 2008: Observational needs for climate prediction and adaptation.
Bulletin of the World Meteorological Organization, 57(1), 17-21.
Trope, Y. and N. Liberman, 2003: Temporal construal. Psychological Review, 110(3),
403-421.
Turpie, J.K., C. Marais, and J.N. Blignaut, 2008: The Working for Water Programme:
evolution of a payments for ecosystem services mechanism that addresses both
poverty and ecosystem service delivery in South Africa. Ecological Economics,
65, 788-798.
Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman, 1974: Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and
biases. Science, New Series, 185(4157), 1124-1131.
Tversky, A. and E. Shafir, 1992: Choice under conflict: the dynamics of deferred
decision. Psychological Science, 3(6), 358-361.
UNDP, 2007: Human Development Report 2007/08: Fighting Climate Change: Human
Solidarity in a Divided World. United Nations Development Programme (UNDP),
Palgrave McMillan, New York, NY, USA, 384 pp.
UNDP, 2009: UNDP Methodology Guidebook for the Assessment of Investment and
Financial Flows to Address Climate Change. Version 1.0, United Nations
Development Programme (UNDP), New York, NY, USA, 56 pp.
UNEP, 2006: Marine and Coastal Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: A Synthesis
Report Based on the Findings of the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. United
Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), Nairobi, Kenya, 64 pp.
UNFCCC, 2002: Annotated Guidelines for the Preparation of National Adaptation
Programmes of Action. Decision 28/CP.7, Least Developed Countries Expert
Group, United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC),
UNFCCC Secretariat, Bonn, Germany, 41 pp., unfccc.int/files/cooperation_and_
support/ldc/application/pdf/annguide.pdf.
UNFCCC, 2007: Investment and Financial Flows to Address Climate Change. Background
paper on the analysis of existing and planned investment and financial flows
relevant to the development of effective and appropriate international response
to climate change, United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
(UNFCCC), UNFCCC Secretariat, Bonn, Germany, 272 pp.
UNFCCC, 2008: Investment and Financial Flows to Address Climate Change: An
Update. Technical Paper, Bonn Document No. FCCC/TP/2008/7, 26 November
2008, United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC),
UNFCCC Secretariat, Bonn, Germany, 111 pp.
Verheyen, R., 2002: Adaptation to the impacts of anthropogenic climate change –
the international legal framework. Review of European Community &
International Environmental Law, 11(2), 129-143.
Verheyen, R., 2005: Climate Change Damage and International Law: Prevention
Duties and State Responsibility. Developments in International Law, Vol. 54,
Martinus Nijhoff, Leiden, Germany and Boston, MA, USA, 406 pp.
Verlade, S., Y. Malhi, D. Moran, J. Wright, and S. Hussain, 2005: Valuing the impacts
of climate change on protected areas in Africa. Ecological Economics, 53(1),
21-33.
Viguie, V. and S. Hallegatte, 2012: Trade-offs and synergies in urban climate policies.
Nature Climate Change, 2, 334-337, doi:10.1038/NCLIMATE1434.
Viscusi, W.K. and J.E. Aldy, 2003: The value of a statistical life: a critical review of
market estimates throughout the world. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 5-76.
Vivid Economics, 2010: Promoting Economic Growth when the Climate is Changing.
Report prepared for UK Department of International Development (DIFID) by
Vivid Economics, Vivid Economics, London, UK, 42 pp.
Vorosmarty, C.J., P. Green, J. Salisbury, and R.B. Lammers, 2000: Global water
resources: vulnerability from climate change and population growth. Science,
289, 284-288.
Wang, W.W. and B.A. McCarl, 2013: Temporal investment in climate change adaptation
and mitigation. Climate Change Economics, 04(02), 1350009, doi:10.1142/
S2010007813500097.
Ward, P.J., K.M. Strzepek, W.P. Pauw, L.M. Brander, G.A. Hughes, and J.C.J.H. Aerts,
2010: Partial costs of global climate change adaptation for the supply of raw
industrial and municipal water: a methodology and application. Environmental
Research Letters, 5(4), 044011, doi:10.1088/1748-9326/5/4/044011.
Watkiss, P. (ed.), 2011: The Climate Cost Project. Final Report, Volume 1: Europe.
Published by the Stockholm Environment Institute (SEI), Stockholm, Sweden,
ISBN 978-91-86125-35-6, www.climatecost.cc/reportsandpublications.html.
Watkiss, P. and A. Hunt, 2010: Review of Adaptation Costs and Benefits Estimates
in Europe for SOER 2010. Contribution to the EEA SOER 2010, Report prepared
for the European Environment Agency (EEA) under the Framework contract for
economic support (EEA/IEA/09/002) – Lot 2 ‘Climate change adaptation: costs
and benefits’, Metroeconomica Economic and Environmental Consultants and
Paul Watkiss Associates, Bath, UK, 74 pp.
Weitzman, M.L., 2009: On modeling and interpreting the economics of catastrophic
climate change. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, 1-19.
West, C.T. and D.G. Lenze, 1994: Modeling the regional impact of natural disasters
and recovery: a general framework and an application to Hurricane Andrew.
International Regional Science Review, 17(2), 121-150.
West, J.J., M.J. Small, and H. Dowlatabadi, 2001: Storms, investor decisions, and the
economic impacts of sea level rise. Climatic Change, 48, 317-342.
White, H. and E. Masset, 2008: An Impact Evaluation of India’s Second And Third
Andhra Pradesh Irrigation: A Case of Poverty Reduction with Low Economic
Returns. The World Bank Independent Evaluation Group (IEG), The International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC,
USA, 130 pp.
Wilbanks, T., 2007: Scale and sustainability. Climate Policy, 7(4), 278-287.
Wilbanks, T., 2010: Research and development priorities for climate change mitigation
and adaptation. In: Dealing with Climate Change: Setting a Global Agenda for
Mitigation and Adaptation [Pachauri, R. (ed.)]. The Energy Resources Institute
(TERI), TERI Press, New Delhi, India, pp. 77-99.
Wilbanks, T. and J. Sathaye, 2007: Integrating mitigation and adaptation as responses
to climate change: a synthesis. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global
Change, 12(5), 957-962.
Wilby, R.L. and S. Dessai, 2010: Robust adaptation to climate change. Weather, 65,
180-185.
Williamson, O.E., 1979: Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual
relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233-261.
Willows, R. and R. Connell (eds.), 2003: Climate Adaptation: Risk, Uncertainty and
Decision-Making. UKCIP Technical Report, UK Climate Impacts Programme
(UKCIP), UKCIP, Oxford, UK, 154 pp., www.ukcip.org.uk/wordpress/wp-
content/PDFs/UKCIP-Risk-framework.pdf.
Wing, I.S. and K. Fisher-Vanden, 2013: Confronting the challenge of integrated as-
sessment of climate adaptation: a conceptual framework. Climatic Change,
117(3), 497-514.
World Bank, 2006: Clean Energy and Development: Towards an Investment
Framework. DC2006-0002, prepared for the April 5, 2006 meeting of the
Development Committee, Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development
Vice Presidency, Infrastructure Vice Presidency, The International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 146
pp.
World Bank, 2007: Results of Preparation Work on the Design of a Caribbean
Catastrophe Risk Insurance Facility. Background document, The International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC,
USA, 68 pp.
World Bank, 2009: World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate
Change. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The
World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 417 pp.
World Bank, 2010a: Economics of Adaptation to Climate Change: Synthesis Report.
The World Bank Group, Washington, DC, USA, 136 pp., climatechange.
worldbank.org/sites/default/files/documents/EACCSynthesisReport.pdf.
World Bank, 2010b: Economics of Adaptation to Climate Change: Bangladesh,
Vol. 1, Main Report. The World Bank Group, Washington, DC, USA, 102 pp.,
climatechange.worldbank.org/sites/default/files/documents/EACC_Bangladesh.
pdf.
World Bank, 2010c: Economics of Adaptation to Climate Change: Samoa. The World
Bank Group, Washington, DC, USA, 58 pp., climatechange.worldbank.org/
sites/default/files/documents/EACC_Samoa.pdf.
World Bank, 2010d: Economics of Adaptation to Climate Change: Vietnam. The World
Bank Group, Washington, DC, USA, 84 pp., climatechange.worldbank.org/sites/
default/files/documents/EACC_Vietnam.pdf.
World Bank, 2012: Inclusive Green Growth: The Pathway to Sustainable Development.
The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 171 pp.
World Bank, 2013: World Development Report 2014: Risk and Opportunities
Managing Risk for Development. The International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development / The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA, 343 pp.
977
17
Economics of Adaptation Chapter 17
World Bank and United Nations, 2010: Natural Hazards UnNatural Disasters: The
Economics of Effective Prevention. The World Bank and the United Nations, The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank,
Washington, DC, USA, 254 pp.
WUCA, 2010: Decision Support Planning Methods: Incorporating Climate Change
Uncertainties into Water Planning. Water Utility Climate Alliance (WUCA), San
Francisco, CA, USA, 102 pp.
Wunder, S., 2005: Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts. CIFOR
Occasional Paper No. 42, Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR),
Bogor, Indonesia, 24 pp.
Wunder, S. and M. Albán, 2008: Decentralized payments for environmental services:
the cases of Pimampiro and PROFAFOR in Ecuador. Ecological Economics,
65(4), 685-698.
Wunder, S. and J. Börner, 2011: Ch. 11: Changing land uses in forestry and agriculture
through payments for environmental service. In: Climate Change and Land
Policies [Ingram, G.K. and Y.-H. Hong (eds.)]. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy,
Cambridge, MA, USA, pp. 277-304, www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2042_1364_
LP2010-ch11-Changing-Land-Uses-in-Forestry-and-Agriculture-Through-
Payments-for-Environmental-Services.pdf.
Wunder, S., S. Engel, and S. Pagiola, 2008: Taking stock: A comparative analysis of
payments for environmental services programs in developed and developing
countries. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 834-852.
Wünscher, T., S. Engel, and S. Wunder, 2008: Spatial targeting of payments for
environmental services: a tool for boosting conservation benefits. Ecological
Economics, 65, 822-833.
Yohe, G. and R. Leichenko, 2010: Adopting a risk-based approach. Annals of the New
York Academy of Sciences, 1196, 29-40.
Yohe, G., J. Neumann, and H. Ameden, 1995: Assessing the economic cost of
greenhouse induced sea level rise: methods and applications in support of a
national survey. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,
29(Suppl.), S78-S97.
Yohe, G., J. Neumann, P. Marshall, and H. Ameden, 1996: The economic cost of
greenhouse induced sea level rise in the United States. Climatic Change, 32,
387-410.
Yohe, G., K. Knee, and P. Kirshen, 2011: On the economics of coastal adaptation
solutions in an uncertain world. Climatic Change, 106(1), 71-92.
Zhang, Y.W., A.D. Hagerman, and B.A. McCarl, 2013: How climate factors influence the
spatial distribution of Texas cattle breeds, Climatic Change, 118(2), 183-195.